首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   209篇
  免费   9篇
  国内免费   5篇
化学   6篇
力学   2篇
综合类   4篇
数学   169篇
物理学   42篇
  2023年   2篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   4篇
  2020年   4篇
  2019年   4篇
  2018年   5篇
  2017年   7篇
  2016年   2篇
  2015年   3篇
  2014年   8篇
  2013年   28篇
  2012年   14篇
  2011年   14篇
  2010年   12篇
  2009年   12篇
  2008年   16篇
  2007年   29篇
  2006年   7篇
  2005年   10篇
  2004年   4篇
  2003年   4篇
  2002年   5篇
  2001年   4篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   1篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   1篇
  1995年   5篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   2篇
  1992年   2篇
  1990年   1篇
  1988年   2篇
排序方式: 共有223条查询结果,搜索用时 734 毫秒
31.
In this paper, we analyze market efficiency for the Shanghai stock market over time using a model-free method known as multifractal detrended fluctuation analysis. Through analyzing the change of scale behavior, we find that the price-limited reform improved the efficiency in the long term, but the influence in the short term was very minor. Employing the method of moving window, using three different measures we find that the Shanghai stock market became more and more efficient after the reform. We also implement the same procedure on volatility series and find the evidence of inefficiency.  相似文献   
32.
Natural disasters increase in number and severity. Studies have shown the failure of the catastrophe insurance market by listing many causes or through developing economic models (Charpentier and Le Maux, 2014; Kousky and Cooke, 2012; Ibragimov et al., 2009). However, they have not considered the effect of the following factors on market equilibrium: advanced disaster-resistant technologies used by insureds, alternative financial innovations employed by insurers, and various disaster policies that are implemented by governments. To fill this gap, this study examines how these three factors affect the market equilibrium by changing the supply of, and demand for insurance and determines which factor(s) contributes to the market equilibrium. Furthermore, we derive the formula of position size which gives criteria for selecting index-based contracts. Overall annual numbers and insured losses of catastrophes are collected by peril type and by occurrence region listed in Sigma, which is issued by Swiss Re annually. The comparative static equilibrium analysis demonstrates that the improvement of market equilibrium is significant at low level of loss correlation in all cases. The empirical findings give insurers good references for business and geographical diversification in portfolio of catastrophe insurance policies.  相似文献   
33.
Widely cited evidence for scaling (self-similarity) of the returns of stocks and other securities is inconsistent with virtually all currently-used models for price movements. In particular, state-of-the-art models provide for ubiquitous, irregular, and oftentimes high-frequency fluctuations in volatility (“stochastic volatility”), both intraday and across the days, weeks, and years over which data is aggregated in demonstrations of self-similarity of returns. Stochastic volatility renders these models, which are based on variants and generalizations of random walks, incompatible with self-similarity. We show here that empirical evidence for self-similarity does not actually contradict the analytic lack of self-similarity in these models. The resolution of the mismatch between models and data can be traced to a statistical consequence of aggregating large amounts of non-stationary data.  相似文献   
34.
We first present prima facie evidence for the predictions generated by the mixture of distributions hypothesis, using daily German stock returns and their corresponding daily trading volumes and number of trades. These last two variables are used as proxies for the stochastic rate of information arrival when one wishes to explain GARCH effects by adhering to the mixture of distributions hypothesis. We show that there is no need for these proxies when the stochastic rate of information arrival follows an inverted gamma distribution. Daily trading volume and the daily number of trades, however, empirically provide an explanation for the occurrence of conditional heteroskedasticity of the GARCH form. We estimate several specifications where daily trading volume is included in the conditional variance equation additively and multiplicatively. The new multiplicative specification clearly outperforms the additive specification.  相似文献   
35.
Abstract

This paper is concerned with optimal market making in the foreign exchange market. The market maker's holdings in the different currencies are modelled as stochastic processes that are influenced by both the stochastic exchange rates and the stochastic customer buy and sell orders. The market maker can control their own bid and ask price quotes and, additionally, can buy and sell at other market participants' quotes. The resulting stochastic control problem consists of a controlled diffusion problem for the optimal quotes and a singular control problem for optimal trades at other market participants' quotes. A Markov chain approximation is used to derive optimal strategies.  相似文献   
36.
在消费者对商品价格与供货时间的偏好假设下,建立一个厂商关于电子商务与传统商务交易方式选择的完全信息静态博弈模型,其纳什均衡表明了电子商务与传统商务潜在的发展趋势,特别是两者可能的市场剖分关系.确切而言,若市场满足既定假设,均衡条件下的电子商务交易方式表现为较长的供货时间及低于传统商务约40%的市场交易价格,将获得三分之一的市场份额.  相似文献   
37.
Abstract

New concepts of economics such as an average demand matrix of society, strategy of a firm and consumer behaviour, and others are introduced. We give sufficient conditions for technological mapping under which there exist both the Walras equlibrium state and optimal Walras equilibrium one. We obtain the set of equations which equilibrium price vector solves. The theory of interindustry economic equilibrium is developed. The model of economy with regular interests of consumers is proposed.  相似文献   
38.
We construct a jump-diffusion model with seasonality, mean-reversion, time-dependent jump intensity and heteroskedastic disturbance for electricity spot prices, while keeping the analytical tractability of futures prices. We find that the jump component plays a considerably larger role than the diffusion component in the variance of spot prices. Moreover, the jump intensity is much higher during summer and winter. We also explore the seasonal market price of risk (MPR) with different maturities, from one month to five months. Our results show that the diffusion risk and the jump risk are priced quite differently.  相似文献   
39.
In this paper we analyse price fluctuations with the aim of measuring how long the market takes to adjust prices to weak-form efficiency, i.e., how long it takes for prices to adjust to a fractional Brownian motion with a Hurst exponent of 0.5. The Hurst exponent is estimated for different time horizons using detrended fluctuation analysis–a method suitable for non-stationary series with trends–in order to identify at which time scale the Hurst exponent is consistent with the efficient market hypothesis. Using high-frequency share price, exchange rate and stock data, we show how price dynamics exhibited important deviations from efficiency for time periods of up to 15 min; thereafter, price dynamics was consistent with a geometric Brownian motion. The intraday behaviour of the series also indicated that price dynamics at trade opening and close was hardly consistent with efficiency, which would enable investors to exploit price deviations from fundamental values. This result is consistent with intraday volume, volatility and transaction time duration patterns.  相似文献   
40.
At the ultra high frequency level, the notion of price of an asset is very ambiguous. Indeed, many different prices can be defined (last traded price, best bid price, mid price, etc.). Thus, in practice, market participants face the problem of choosing a price when implementing their strategies. In this work, we propose a notion of efficient price which seems relevant in practice. Furthermore, we provide a statistical methodology enabling to estimate this price from the order flow.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号