首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 203 毫秒
1.
Abstract The impact on the value of a fishery from exogenous shocks is investigated. Part of the habitat is protected by a marine reserve, while the remaining fishery is managed by optimal, total allowable catch quotas. Shocks of different, spatial nature and with different probability distributions are investigated. The results suggest that reserves are of minor interest as a management tool when shocks affect the stock uniformly. Reserves may substantially enhance the value of the fishery when shocks are nonuniformly spatially distributed.  相似文献   

2.
We consider an infinite time horizon spatially distributed optimal harvesting problem for a vegetation and soil water reaction diffusion system, with rainfall as the main external parameter. By Pontryagin's maximum principle, we derive the associated four‐component canonical system (CS), and numerically analyze this and hence the optimal control problem in two steps. First, we numerically compute a rather rich bifurcation structure of flat (spatially homogeneous) canonical steady states and patterned canonical steady states (FCSS and PCSS, respectively), in 1D and 2D. Then, we compute time‐dependent solutions of the CS that connect to some FCSS or PCSS. The method is efficient in dealing with nonunique canonical steady states, and thus also with multiple local maxima of the objective function. It turns out that over wide parameter regimes the FCSS, i.e., spatially uniform harvesting, are not optimal. Instead, controlling the system to a PCSS yields a higher profit. Moreover, compared to (a simple model of) private optimization, the social control gives a higher yield, and vegetation survives for much lower rainfall. In addition, the computation of the optimal (social) control gives an optimal tax to incorporate into the private optimization.  相似文献   

3.
ABSTRACT. Given a paucity of empirical data, policymakers are forced to rely on modeling to assess potential impacts of creating marine reserves to manage fisheries. Many modeling studies of reserves conclude that fishing yield will increase (or decrease only modestly) after creating a reserve in a heavily exploited fishery. However, much of the marine reserves modeling ignores the spatial heterogeneity of fishing behavior. Contrary to empirical findings in fisheries science and economics, most models assume explicitly or implicitly that fishing effort is distributed uniformly over space. This paper demonstrates that by ignoring this heterogeneity, yield‐per‐recruit models systematically overstate the yield gains (or understate the losses) from creating a reserve in a heavily exploited fishery. Conversely, at very low levels of exploitation, models that ignore heterogeneous fishing effort overstate the fishing yield losses from creating a reserve. Starting with a standard yield‐per‐recruit model, the paper derives a yield surface that maps spatially differentiated fishing effort into total long‐run fishing yield. It is the curvature of this surface that accounts for why the spatial distribution of fishing effort so greatly affects predicted changes from forming a reserve. The results apply generally to any model in which the long‐run fishing yield has similar curvature to a two‐patch Beverton‐Holt model. A simulation of marine reserve formation in the California red sea urchin fishery with Beverton‐Holt recruitment, eleven patches, and common larval pool dispersal dynamics reinforces these results.  相似文献   

4.
ABSTRACT. Limiting adverse consequences of fishing on essential fish habitat has emerged as a key fishery management objective. The conventional approach to providing habitat protection is to create MPAs or marine reserves that prohibit all or certain types of fishing in specific areas. However, there may be more cost‐effective and flexible ways to provide habitat protection. We propose an individual habitat quota (IHQ) system for habitat conservation that would utilize economic incentives to achieve habitat conservation goals cost‐effectively. Individual quotas of habitat impact units (HIU) would be distributed to fishers with an aggregate quota set to maintain a target habitat “stock.” HIU use would be based on a proxy for marginal habitat damage. We use a dynamic, explicitly spatial fishery and habitat simulation model to explore how such a system might work. We examine how outcomes are affected by spatial heterogeneity in the fishery and the scale of habitat regulation. We find that the IHQ system is a highly cost‐effective means of ensuring a given level of habitat protection, but that spatial heterogeneity and the scale of regulation can have significant effects on the distribution of habitat protection.  相似文献   

5.
ABSTRACT. The excessive and unsustainable exploitation of our marine resources has led to the promotion of marine reserves as a fisheries management tool. Marine reserves, areas in which fishing is restricted or prohibited, can offer opportunities for the recovery of exploited stock and fishery enhancement. In this paper we examine the contribution of fully protected tropical marine reserves to fishery enhancement by modeling marine reserve‐fishery linkages. The consequences of reserve establishment on the long‐run equilibrium fish biomass and fishery catch levels are evaluated. In contrast to earlier models this study highlights the roles of both adult (and juvenile) fish migration and larval dispersal between the reserve and fishing grounds by employing a spawner‐recruit model. Uniform larval dispersal, uniform larval retention and complete larval retention combined with zero, moderate and high fish migration scenarios are analyzed in turn. The numerical simulations are based on Mombasa Marine National Park, Kenya, a fully protected coral reef marine reserve comprising approximately 30% of former fishing grounds. Simulation results suggest that the establishment of a fully protected marine reserve will always lead to an increase in total fish biomass. If the fishery is moderately to heavily exploited, total fishery catch will be greater with the reserve in all scenarios of fish and larval movement. If the fishery faces low levels of exploitation, catches can be optimized without a reserve but with controlled fishing effort. With high fish migration from the reserve, catches are optimized with the reserve. The optimal area of the marine reserve depends on the exploitation rate in the neighboring fishing grounds. For example, if exploitation is maintained at 40%, the ‘optimal’ reserve size would be 10%. If the rate increases to 50%, then the reserve needs to be 30% of the management area in order to maximize catches. However, even in lower exploitation fisheries (below 40%), a small reserve (up to 20%) provides significantly higher gains in fish biomass than losses in catch. Marine reserves are a valuable fisheries management tool. To achieve maximum fishery benefits they should be complemented by fishing effort controls.  相似文献   

6.
ABSTRACT. Fully protected marine reserves, areas that are closed to all fishing, have attracted great interest for their potential to benefit fisheries. A wide range of models suggest reserves will be most effective for species that are relatively sedentary as adults but produce offspring that disperse widely. Adult spawning stocks will be secure from capture in reserves, while their offspring disperse freely into fishing grounds. Such species include animals like reef fish, mollusks and echino‐derms, and models typically indicate that when they are over‐fished, catches will be higher with reserves than without. By contrast, the same models suggest that reserves will be ineffective for animals that are mobile as adults species like cod, tuna or sharks. They remain vulnerable to fishing whenever they move outside reserves. Unfortunately, most models lack sufficient realism to effectively gauge reserve effects on migratory species. They usually assume that individuals are homogeneously distributed in a uniform sea and move randomly. They also assume that fishers hunt at random. Neither is true. For centuries, fishers have targeted places and times when their quarry are most vulnerable to capture. Protecting these sites could have disproportionately large effects on stocks. Furthermore, models rarely take into account possible benefits from improvements in habitat within reserves. Such changes, like increased biomass and complexity of bottom‐living organisms, could alter fish movement patterns and reduce natural mortality rates in ways that enhance reserve benefits. We present a simple model of reserve effects on a migratory fish species. The model incorporates spatial variation in vulnerability to capture and shows that strategically placed reserves can offer benefits in the form of increased spawning stock and catch, especially when fishing intensities are high. We need to develop a new generation of models that incorporate habitat and behaviour to better explore the utility of reserves for mobile species. Migratory behavior does not preclude reserves from benefiting a species, but it demands that we apply different principles in designing them. We must identify critical sites to species and develop reserve networks that focus protection on those places.  相似文献   

7.
合理的油气资源税费能够引导企业优化开发决策,平衡当代与后代利益关系,实现跨期资源有效配置。从跨期油气资源最优分配的角度,通过最优控制理论构建寡头垄断市场中社会福利最大化和企业利润最大化目标下的油气资源开发决策模型,并以社会福利最大化目标下的资源开发决策为基准,研究从价、从量、储量三种不同形式的油气资源税费对资源开发决策的调节作用,研究发现:(1)征收从价税费,最优的从价税率为26.4%,政府既可以保障社会最优,还可以获得较多的税费收入;(2)征收从量税费,从量税率为1.77元/吨,政府可以保证社会福利最大化,但相比从价税费政府的税费收入较少;(3)征收储量税费,社会福利最大化下的储量税费为-0.13元/吨,也就是政府需向企业进行补贴才可以保证社会最优,会形成一定的财政压力。  相似文献   

8.
In this work, we propose and analyze a model related with the management optimization of a renewable resource in aquatic environment composed of two different patches. Spatial distribution of each subpopulation is assumed: one is developed in a marine protected area (MPA) or a marine reserve and the other is located in a zone where fishing with open access may be effected.It is generally assumed that there may be migration between both areas, but in this work we will consider that the flux goes.When a fishing ban in the protected area is established it becomes a marine reserve, which can also be assumed as a refuge for the captured species. In this case, the marine reserve is the source and the exploitation area is a sink.The behavior of the renewable resource is modeled by a deterministic continuous time system. To establish the optimal harvesting policy, we will maximize the present value J of a continuous time stream of revenues, given by a cost functional indicating the net economic revenue to the fishermen, the perceived rent. Using Pontragyn’s Maximum Principle we will obtain the Hamiltonian function to determine the optimal policies.  相似文献   

9.
Two cases of the discrete time finite horizon technology replacement problem are solved. The first deals with two available machines, one in use and a better one that can be purchased to replace it. The second case considers, in addition, a third machine of future technology that will be available at some random future time. The maintenance level of each used machine is chosen for each period in order to economically control performance deterioration. For solving the model, we first derive an optimal preventive maintenance policy by showing that bang-bang (i.e., full or non), non-increasing, maintenance efforts are optimal. Employing the optimal maintenance policy, we reformat the problem and conduct a numerical search in order to derive the replacement policy that will maximize the expected net present profit. Numerical examples demonstrate that management may improve profitability by delaying (but not necessarily foregoing) replacement with an available better machine.  相似文献   

10.
在供应链背景下,易腐品的生产运输协调决策具有非常重要的现实意义,也是近几年研究的热点问题。本文在前人研究的基础上,通过引入安全库存并将其作为决策变量,拓展了易腐品生产运输协调决策模型;并证明了最佳运输批量序列一定是单调不减的及第一次补货时一定要清空库存;进而证明了最佳运输批量序列的具体形式并提出了一种运输策略。本文的目标是在新的运输策略下最大化单一生产商单一零售商供应链系统的利润,找到最佳运输批量、最佳生产时间以及运输次数。最后,本文进行了算例分析,用来验证本文提出的模型。  相似文献   

11.
The simultaneous planning of the production and the maintenance in a flexible manufacturing system is considered in this paper. The manufacturing system is composed of one machine that produces a single product. There is a preventive maintenance plan to reduce the failure rate of the machine. This paper is different from the previous researches in this area in two separate ways. First, the failure rate of the machine is supposed to be a function of its age. Second, we assume that the demand of the manufacturing product is time dependent and its rate depends on the level of advertisement on that product. The objective is to maximize the expected discounted total profit of the firm over an infinite time horizon. In the process of finding a solution to the problem, we first characterize an optimal control by introducing a set of Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman partial differential equations. Then we realize that under practical assumptions, this set of equations can not be solved analytically. Thus to find a suboptimal control, we approximate the original stochastic optimal control model by a discrete-time deterministic optimal control problem. Then proposing a numerical method to solve the steady state Riccati equation, we approximate a suboptimal solution to the problem.  相似文献   

12.
Abstract The purpose of this paper is to introduce the impact of fishing activity on a marine ecosystem. The fishing activity is considered not only through annual harvest but also through a second component, called the degree of protection of the fishery environment. This characterizes the environmental impact of fishing. A stochastic dynamic programming problem is presented in infinite horizon, where a sole owner seeks to maximize a discounted expected profit. The main hypothesis states that the stock–recruitment relationship is stochastic and that both components of the fishing activity have an impact on the probability law of the state of the fishery environment. The optimal fishing policy is obtained and compared with standard models. This optimal policy has the following properties: is not a constant escapement policy and indicates an element of self‐protection by the fishery manager. The paper ends with a discussion on the existence of degrees of protection of the fishery environment that take into account the environmental conservation and preservation of economic activity.  相似文献   

13.
A hierarchical economic–environmental model is formulated to analyze the sustainable management of farming production in a landlord–tenant system. The problem under study is interdisciplinary and combines various agricultural, economic, social, and environmental factors. To maximize profit, the landlord chooses a rental payment and the duration of a lease contract. Tenants invest into farmyard fertilizer in order to improve future crop growth and maximize their profit. It is shown that the qualitative behavior of optimal trajectories in the landlord–tenant problem is mostly affected by environmental conditions rather than by the end‐of‐horizon and delay effects. A range of model parameters is identified, where the optimal trajectory coincides with the first‐best environmentally and socially efficient solution.  相似文献   

14.
The dynamics of four source–sink models for an exploited resource under a constant fishing effort are here presented. Two models are described by ordinary differential equations; the other two are expressed by impulsive differential equations systems. A continuous time growth function for the resource is assumed for each of the four model. The impulsiveness in the harvest activity among fixed seasonal closures were considered in the models expressed by impulsive differential equations. We note that all our models show the possibility of getting a sustainable resource exploitation. The results obtained using both techniques are compared. These metapopulation models suggest the convenience of considering the source patches as marine reserves, in order to preserve the renewable resources.  相似文献   

15.
研究零售商具有风险偏好行为下,同时考虑价格、质量和服务水平的供应链联合决策问题。运用均值-CVaR准则来刻画零售商风险偏好行为,它包括风险厌恶、风险中性和风险追求,同时具有损失规避的特性。首先得到供应链集中系统、制造商提供服务(模型$\mbox{I}$)和零售商提供服务(模型$\mbox{II}$)下的最优决策和最优利润(期望效用)。其次,证明了成本共担契约在零售商风险厌恶时可以实现供应链协调.第三,对模型$\mbox{I}$和模型$\mbox{II}$协调后的最优利润(期望效用)进行比较,证明两种模型下制造商利润相同,而与模型$\mbox{I}$相比,模型$\mbox{II}$下零售商获得更多的期望效用。最后,数值例子证明了得到的研究结果。  相似文献   

16.
在短缺量拖后率是等待时间的负指数函数、订购成本是批量的线性函数的条件下,建立了带数量折扣的腐烂物质库存模型,目标是优化总平均利润.在给定销售价格的情况下,证明了库存系统的最优补货策略存在且唯一;且若采用最优补货策略,平均利润函数是销售价格的凹函数;最后给出了模型的算法,并用数值例子说明了模型和算法的有效性.  相似文献   

17.
针对两类供应风险(不确定产能与随机产出率)下装配制造商的零部件订购决策这一难题,运用随机非线性规划方法,以装配商期望利润最大化为目标,建立零部件订购决策的多维优化模型,刻画了确定需求下的最优订购量,并对其进行了灵敏性分析。最后,通过数值算例验证了模型结论并进一步探讨不同类供应风险的影响,为装配商的零部件订购决策和风险管理提供有益的管理启示。  相似文献   

18.
本文考虑由单一供应商和零售商组成的供应链系统,当供应商为零售商提供回购契约,同时零售商又为下游顾客提供商业信用契约时,供应商如何设计回购契约来有效协调整个供应链,以及零售商又如何借助回购和商业信用契约来做出自身最优订货策略问题,并建立了相应的决策模型。通过模型分析,给出了供应商和零售商在四种情形下的最优契约设计参数,以及零售商的最优订货决策。研究发现,当满足一定的参数范围时,供应链中两主体同时采用协调契约能够更加有效地增加整个供应链中的订货量和利润,为各主体创造更多新的价值。最后,本文结合数值例子,分析了模型参数变化对最优订货策略和各主体利润的影响。  相似文献   

19.
A collaborative inventory system of single vendor and single buyer is developed to maximize the total profit of the whole system. However, the optimal solution for the whole system is not always beneficial to both players. To ensure mutual benefit, a negotiation factor is incorporated to share the profit between the two players according to their contributions. The permissible delay in payment is a win–win strategy for sharing profit in the collaborative system. A deteriorating inventory model with finite replenishment rate and price sensitive demand is assumed to occur in a high-tech, short life cycle and perishable electronic product. A numerical example is provided to illustrate our models. The sensitivity analysis of the demand rate, replenishment rate, deterioration factor, and other related parameters shows that the percentage extra total profit is significant when both the collaboration strategy and the deterioration factor are considered.  相似文献   

20.
Spatial structure tends to have a stabilizing influence on predator–prey interactions in which the local model predicts extinction of the system. This result is well supported by laboratory observations of simple systems. Here, we use a spatially explicit version of the Nicholson–Bailey model having Moran–Ricker host reproduction to repeat and extend some of these results. Our model is a discrete spatial convolution model analogous to the integrodifference equations (IDEs) used by other authors. We show a spatial rescue effect which prevents extinction of the system by reducing the size (standard deviation) of the dispersal pdf. We also show that very favorable habitat (K=∞) and marginal habitat (K=1.0), when mixed randomly together in an explicit map, are highly stabilizing whereas either kind of habitat alone will cause extinction. The marginal habitat in this situation has host densities below parasite replacement level and thus constitutes a host refuge (although not a complete one) from the parasite. When a host–parasitoid model having spiral wave dynamics in two-dimensional space was extended to one- and three-dimensional space, we observed analogous dynamics, i.e., traveling waves of evasion and pursuit in one dimension and ‘spiral-like’ structures in a three-dimensional spatial volume. We illustrate an approach to analysis of spatial convolution models via the frequency response of the system transfer function. In spatial convolution format, local interaction and dispersal are conveniently isolated from one another, and this allows us to vary these components independently and thus to study their effects on the dynamics of the total system. We show two examples of nonrandom dispersal pdf’s – a bimodal form representing two dispersal types in the population and a ‘ripple’ pdf representing a repulsive process.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号