首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   187篇
  免费   1篇
化学   109篇
晶体学   1篇
力学   11篇
数学   33篇
物理学   34篇
  2023年   1篇
  2021年   1篇
  2019年   2篇
  2018年   1篇
  2017年   2篇
  2016年   1篇
  2014年   4篇
  2013年   12篇
  2012年   6篇
  2011年   8篇
  2010年   2篇
  2009年   4篇
  2008年   16篇
  2007年   11篇
  2006年   9篇
  2005年   4篇
  2004年   10篇
  2003年   6篇
  2002年   8篇
  2000年   1篇
  1999年   3篇
  1998年   1篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   1篇
  1994年   3篇
  1993年   3篇
  1992年   2篇
  1989年   1篇
  1988年   1篇
  1985年   8篇
  1984年   3篇
  1983年   5篇
  1982年   2篇
  1981年   5篇
  1980年   1篇
  1979年   1篇
  1978年   3篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   4篇
  1975年   3篇
  1974年   5篇
  1973年   5篇
  1972年   5篇
  1971年   3篇
  1970年   3篇
  1966年   2篇
排序方式: 共有188条查询结果,搜索用时 724 毫秒
111.
The paper considers the optimal resource distribution between increasing protection of genuine elements and deploying decoys (false targets) in a situation when the attacker's and defender's resources are stockpiling and the resource increment rate is constant. It is assumed that the system must perform within an exogenously given time horizon and the attack time probability is uniformly distributed over this horizon. Series and parallel systems are considered. The defender optimizes the resource distribution in order to minimize the system vulnerability. The attacker cannot distinguish genuine and false elements and can attack a randomly chosen subset of the elements.  相似文献   
112.
We present a novel model capable of distinguishing between the effects of negative incentives (“sticks”) and positive incentives (“carrots”) for influencing the behavior of intelligent and adaptable adversaries. Utilities are developed for the defender and the terrorist. The defender is assumed to have a unit cost of defense, and unit costs of providing negative and positive incentives. The terrorist likewise has a unit cost of attack, which may either increase or decrease if the defender provides negative incentives, and enjoys a unit benefit of positive incentives. We show that the potential for perverse effects of counterterrorism (e.g., the emergence of hatred) can cause defenders to rely on positive incentives and decrease their reliance on negative incentives at equilibrium, with use of negative incentives completely eliminated in situations where these would be moderately effective when applied. With low potential for perverse effects of counterterrorism, the defender should rely on effective negative incentives.  相似文献   
113.
One defender defends, and multiple heterogeneous attackers attack, an asset. Three scenarios are considered: the agents move simultaneously; the defender moves first; or the attackers move first. We show how the agents’ unit costs of defense and attack, their asset evaluations, and the number of attackers influence their investments, profits, and withdrawal decisions. Withdrawal does not occur in one-period (simultaneous) games between two agents, at least with the commonly used ratio-form contest success function, but can occur in two-period games between two agents. The presence of one particularly strong attacker can cause other attackers to withdraw from the contest if the advantaged attacker appropriates so much of the defender’s asset that it is no longer sufficiently attractive to interest other attackers. In such cases, the defender focuses exclusively on the strong attacker. An advantaged defender may be able to deter attacks by moving first, but will continue to suffer from attacks if moving second. This suggests the importance of proactive rather than reactive defense.  相似文献   
114.
115.
Two agents protect and attack a collection of assets overarchingly versus individually. Examples of overarching protection are border security, counter intelligence, and public health measures. Both layers of protection have to be breached for an attack to be successful. We consider a simultaneous game, and a two period game with overarching contest in period 1 and individual contests in period 2 if the attacker wins period 1. With reasonable assumptions, such as contest intensities not exceeding one, the defender prefers two protection layers, while the attacker prefers one protection layer. When the unit effort costs of overarching protection and attack are equal, and the agents’ valuations for each asset are equal, in the simultaneous game defender and attacker efforts are equal in the overarching contest. In contrast, for the two period game, the defender invests more than the attacker in the overarching contest to prevent the occurrence of period 2. If the attacker nevertheless wins period 1, both agents exert larger efforts in period 2 compared with the individual contests in the simultaneous game. Framed within the Colonel Blotto literature, the attacker must win the first battlefield (overarching contest) in order to engage in the contests over the n other battlefields (individual contests).  相似文献   
116.
The transformation of n-decane was carried out on bifunctional Pt-HBEA catalysts obtained either by exchange of the HBEA zeolite with Pt, or by mixing various amounts of the HBEA zeolite with a Pt-impregnated alumina. Pt-exchanged HBEA was the most selective catalyst for n-decane isomerisation, which can be explained by a better proximity between acidic and hydrogenating sites and by a fast desorption of monobranched isomers through the small crystallites of the HBEA zeolite.  相似文献   
117.
The signal to noise ratio (SNR) of a multiplexed fiber-optic sensor network can be improved by inserting fiber-optic amplifiers. Several configurations of amplifiers in the sensor network are analyzed. A single fiber-optic amplifier used as a preamplifier is a good solution with high SNR. However, by distributing amplifiers in the network even higher SNR can be obtained, and identical couplers can be used throughout the network.  相似文献   
118.
Ethene homopolymerization and copolymerization with 1‐hexene were performed with three new tetramethyldisilylene‐bridged zirconocene catalysts with 2‐indenyl ligand ( A ), 2‐tetrahydroindenyl ligand ( B ), and tetramethyl‐cyclopentadienyl ligand ( C ) and with methylaluminoxane as a cocatalyst. Catalysts A and B showed substantial comonomer incorporation, resulting in a copolymer melting temperature more than 20° lower than that of the corresponding homopolymer. In contrast, catalyst C produced a copolymer with a low 1‐hexene content and a high melting temperature. The reduction in the molecular weight with 1‐hexene addition also correlated well with the comonomer incorporation. For all three catalysts, the homopolymer and copolymer unsaturations indicated frequent chain termination after 1‐hexene insertion and a high degree of chain‐end isomerization during the homopolymerization of ethene. The chain transfer to Al in the cocatalyst also appeared to be important. The comonomer response could be correlated with the structural properties of the catalyst, as derived from quantum chemical calculations. A linear model, calibrated against recent experiments with unbridged (MenC5H5?n)2ZrCl2 catalysts, suggested that the low comonomer incorporation obtained with catalyst C was caused partly by a narrow opening angle between the aromatic ligands and partly by steric hindrance in the transition state of comonomer insertion. © 2003 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. J Polym Sci Part A: Polym Chem 41: 1622–1631, 2003  相似文献   
119.
A turbulent piloted methane/air diffusion flame (Sandia Flame D) is calculated using both compressible Reynolds-averaged and large-eddy simulations (RAS and LES, respectively). The Eddy Dissipation Concept (EDC) is used for the turbulence-chemistry interaction, which assumes that molecular mixing and the subsequent combustion occur in the fine structures (smaller dissipative eddies, which are close to the Kolmogorov length scales). Assuming the full turbulence energy cascade, the characteristic length and velocity scales of the fine structures are evaluated using a standard k- ?? turbulence model for RAS and a one-equation eddy-viscosity sub-grid scale model for LES. Finite-rate chemical kinetics are taken into account by treating the fine structures as constant pressure and adiabatic homogeneous reactors (calculated as a system of ordinary-differential equations (ODEs)) described by a Perfectly Stirred Reactor (PSR) concept. A robust implicit Runge-Kutta method (RADAU5) is used for integrating stiff ODEs to evaluate reaction rates. The radiation heat transfer is treated by the P1-approximation. The assumed β-PDF approach is applied to assess the influence of modeling of the turbulence-chemistry interaction. Numerical results are compared with available experimental data. In general, there is good agreement between present simulations and measurements both for RAS and LES, which gives a good indication on the adequacy and accuracy of the method and its further application for turbulent combustion simulations.  相似文献   
120.
The complex solution method of Okubo for the deflection of a thin circular aelotropic plate with simply supported edge and uniform lateral load was extended to an elliptic plate by Ohasi. In his work however several inconsistencies appear, of which at least one disqualifies a central part. From a revisit to the works of Okubo and Ohasi a new solution for the deflection of a thin elliptic aelotropic plate with simply supported edge and uniform lateral load emerged. The solution is a generalisation of Okubo’s solution and is valid for any angle between material and geometric principal axes. Previously known solutions, including those for circular plates, are reproduced as special cases of the new solution and results of numerical calculations in new situations appear reasonable.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号