共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
V. Alfi M. Cristelli L. Pietronero A. Zaccaria 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2009,67(3):385-397
We introduce a minimal agent based model for financial markets to understand the nature and self-organization of the stylized
facts. The model is minimal in the sense that we try to identify the essential ingredients to reproduce the most important
deviations of price time series from a random walk behavior. We focus on four essential ingredients: fundamentalist agents
which tend to stabilize the market; chartist agents which induce destabilization; analysis of price behavior for the two strategies;
herding behavior which governs the possibility of changing strategy. Bubbles and crashes correspond to situations dominated
by chartists, while fundamentalists provide a long time stability (on average). The stylized facts are shown to correspond
to an intermittent behavior which occurs only for a finite value of the number of agents N. Therefore they correspond to finite
size effects which, however, can occur at different time scales. We propose a new mechanism for the self-organization of this
state which is linked to the existence of a threshold for the agents to be active or not active. The feedback between price
fluctuations and number of active agents represents a crucial element for this state of self-organized intermittency. The
model can be easily generalized to consider more realistic variants. 相似文献
2.
R. Stresing D. Lindenberger R. Kümmel 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2008,66(2):279-287
Cointegration analysis is applied to the linear combinations of the time series of (the logarithms of) output, capital, labor,
and energy for Germany, Japan, and the USA since 1960.
The computed cointegration vectors represent the output elasticities of the aggregate energy-dependent Cobb-Douglas function.
The output elasticities give the economic weights of the production factors capital, labor, and energy. We find that they
are for labor much smaller and for energy much larger than the cost shares of these factors. In standard economic theory output
elasticities equal cost shares. Our heterodox findings support results obtained with LINEX production functions. 相似文献
3.
M. Bartolozzi 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,57(3):337-345
Avalanches, or Avalanche-like, events are often
observed in the dynamical behaviour of many complex systems which
span from solar flaring to the Earth's crust dynamics and from
traffic flows to financial markets. Self-organized criticality
(SOC) is one of the most popular theories able to explain this
intermittent charge/discharge behaviour. Despite a large amount of
theoretical work, empirical tests for SOC are still in their
infancy. In the present paper we address the common problem of
revealing SOC from a simple time series without having much
information about the underlying system. As a working example we
use a modified version of the multifractal random walk originally
proposed as a model for the stock market dynamics. The study
reveals, despite the lack of the typical ingredients of SOC, an
avalanche-like dynamics similar to that of many physical systems.
While, on one hand, the results confirm the relevance of cascade
models in representing turbulent-like phenomena, on the other,
they also raise the question about the current state of
reliability of SOC inference from time series analysis. 相似文献
4.
M. B. Gordon J. R. Iglesias V. Semeshenko J. P. Nadal 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2009,68(1):133-144
Crime is an economically relevant activity. It may represent a mechanism of wealth distribution but also a social and economic
burden because of the interference with regular legal activities and the cost of the law enforcement system. Sometimes it
may be less costly for the society to allow for some level of criminality. However, a drawback of such a policy is that it
may lead to a high increase of criminal activity, that may become hard to reduce later on. Here we investigate the level of
law enforcement required to keep crime within acceptable limits. A sharp phase transition is observed as a function of the
probability of punishment. We also analyze other consequences of criminality as the growth of the economy, the inequality
in the wealth distribution (the Gini coefficient) and other relevant quantities under different scenarios of criminal activity
and probabilities of apprehension. 相似文献
5.
Stylized facts from a threshold-based heterogeneous agent model 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
R. Cross M. Grinfeld H. Lamba T. Seaman 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,57(2):213-218
A class of heterogeneous agent models is investigated where investors switch trading position whenever their motivation to
do so exceeds some critical threshold. These motivations can be psychological in nature or reflect behaviour suggested by
the efficient market hypothesis (EMH).
By introducing different propensities into a baseline model that displays EMH behaviour, one can attempt to isolate their
effects upon the market dynamics.
The simulation results indicate that the introduction of a herding propensity results in excess kurtosis and power-law decay
consistent with those observed in actual return distributions, but not in significant long-term volatility correlations. Possible
alternatives for introducing such long-term volatility correlations are then identified and discussed. 相似文献
6.
J. Reichardt D. R. White 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,60(2):217-224
We present a framework for automatically decomposing (“block-modeling”) the functional classes of agents within a complex
network. These classes are represented by the nodes of an image graph (“block model”) depicting the main patterns of connectivity
and thus functional roles in the network. Using a first principles approach, we derive a measure for the fit of a network
to any given image graph allowing objective hypothesis testing. From the properties of an optimal fit, we derive how to find
the best fitting image graph directly from the network and present a criterion to avoid overfitting. The method can handle
both two-mode and one-mode data, directed and undirected as well as weighted networks and allows for different types of links
to be dealt with simultaneously. It is non-parametric and computationally efficient. The concepts of structural equivalence
and modularity are found as special cases of our approach. We apply our method to the world trade network and analyze the
roles individual countries play in the global economy. 相似文献
7.
E. W. Piotrowski M. Schroeder 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,57(2):201-203
Kelly criterion, that maximizes the expectation value of the
logarithm of wealth for bookmaker bets, gives an advantage over
different class of strategies. We use projective symmetries for a
explanation of this fact. Kelly's approach
allows for an interesting financial interpretation of the
Boltzmann/Shannon entropy. A “no-go” hypothesis for big
investors is suggested. 相似文献
8.
G.-H. Mu W. Chen J. Kertész W.-X. Zhou 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2009,68(1):145-152
The distributions of trade sizes and trading volumes are investigated based on the limit order book data of 22 liquid Chinese
stocks listed on the Shenzhen Stock Exchange in the whole year 2003. We observe that the size distribution of trades for individualstocks
exhibits jumps, which is caused by the number preference of traders when placing orders. We analyze the applicability of the
“q-Gamma” function for fitting the distribution by the Cramér-von Mises criterion. The empirical PDFs of tradingvolumes at
different timescales Δt ranging from 1 min to 240 min can be well modeled. The applicability of the q-Gamma functions for
multiple trades is restricted to the transaction numbers Δn≤ 8. We find that all the PDFs have power-law tails for large volumes.
Using careful estimation of the average tail exponents α of the distributions of trade sizes and trading volumes, we get α>
2, well outside the Lévy regime. 相似文献
9.
G.-F. Gu W. Chen W.-X. Zhou 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,57(1):81-87
The statistical properties of the bid-ask spread of a
frequently traded Chinese stock listed on the Shenzhen Stock
Exchange are investigated using the limit-order book data. Three
different definitions of spread are considered based on the time
right before transactions, the time whenever the highest buying
price or the lowest selling price changes, and a fixed time
interval. The results are qualitatively similar no matter linear
prices or logarithmic prices are used. The average spread exhibits
evident intraday patterns consisting of a big L-shape in morning
transactions and a small L-shape in the afternoon. The distributions
of the spread with different definitions decay as power laws. The
tail exponents of spreads at transaction level are well within the
interval (2,3) and that of average spreads are well in line with
the inverse cubic law for different time intervals. Based on the
detrended fluctuation analysis, we found the evidence of long memory
in the bid-ask spread time series for all three definitions, even
after the removal of the intraday pattern. Using the classical
box-counting approach for multifractal analysis, we show that the
time series of bid-ask spread do not possess multifractal nature. 相似文献
10.
F. Petroni M. Serva 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2006,51(4):601-608
The present study shows how the information on `hidden' market variables effects optimal investment strategies. We take the
point of view of two investors, one who has access to the hidden variables and one who only knows the quotes of a given asset.
Following Kelly's theory on investment strategies, the Shannon information and the doubling investment rate are quantified
for both investors. Thanks to his privileged knowledge, the first investor can follow a better investment strategy. Nevertheless,
the second investor can extract some of the hidden information looking at the past history of the asset variable. Unfortunately,
due to the complexity of his strategy, this investor will have computational difficulties when he tries to apply it. He will
than follow a simplified strategy, based only on the average sign of the last l quotes of the asset. This results have been
tested with some Monte Carlo simulations. 相似文献
11.
I. Simonsen P. T.H. Ahlgren M. H. Jensen R. Donangelo K. Sneppen 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,57(2):153-158
The value of stocks, indices and other assets, are examples of stochastic processes with unpredictable dynamics. In this paper,
we
discuss asymmetries in short term price movements that can not be
associated with a long term positive trend. These empirical
asymmetries predict that stock index drops are more common on a
relatively short time scale than the corresponding raises. We
present several empirical examples of such asymmetries. Furthermore,
a simple model featuring occasional short periods of synchronized
dropping prices for all stocks constituting the index is introduced
with the aim of explaining these facts. The collective negative
price movements are imagined triggered by external factors in our
society, as well as internal to the economy, that create fear of the
future among investors. This is parameterized by a “fear factor”
defining the frequency of synchronized events. It is demonstrated
that such a simple fear factor model can reproduce several empirical
facts concerning index asymmetries. It is also pointed out that in
its simplest form, the model has certain shortcomings. 相似文献
12.
S. Alfarano T. Lux F. Wagner 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,55(2):183-187
The present paper expands on recent attempts at
estimating the parameters of simple interacting-agent models of
financial markets [S. Alfarano, T. Lux, F. Wagner, Computational Economics 26, 19 (2005); S. Alfarano, T. Lux, F. Wagner, in Funktionsf?higkeit und
Stabilit?t von Finanzm?rkten, edited by W. Franz, H. Ramser,
M. Stadler (Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen, 2005), pp. 241–254]. Here we
provide additional evidence by (i) investigating a large sample of
individual stocks from the Tokyo Stock Exchange, and (ii)
comparing results from the baseline noise trader/fundamentalist
model of [S. Alfarano, T. Lux, F. Wagner, Computational Economics 26, 19 (2005)] with those obtained from an even
simpler version with a preponderance of noise trader behaviour. As
it turns out, this somewhat more parsimonious “maximally skewed”
variant is often not rejected in favor of the more complex
version. We also find that all stocks are dominated by noise
trader behaviour irrespective of whether the data prefer the
skewed or the baseline version of our model. 相似文献
13.
T. Kaizoji 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2006,50(1-2):123-127
In this paper, we quantitatively investigate the properties of a statistical ensemble of stock prices. We focus attention
on the relative price defined as X(t) = S(t)/S(0), where S(0), is the stock price for an onset time of the bubble. We selected
approximately 3200 stocks traded on the Japanese Stock Exchange, and formed a statistical ensemble of daily relative prices
for each trading day in the 3-year period from January 4, 1999 to December 28, 2001, corresponding to the period in which
internet Bubble formed and crashed in the Japanese stock market.
We found that the upper tail of the complementary cumulative distribution function of the ensemble of the relative prices
in the high value of the price is well described by a power-law distribution, P(S>x) ∼x-α , with an exponent that moves over time. Furthermore we found that as the power-law exponents α approached two, the bubble burst. It is reasonable to suppose that it indicates that internet bubble is about to burst. 相似文献
14.
N. Sazuka 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2006,50(1-2):129-131
A non-trivial probability structure is evident in the binary data extracted from the up/down price movements of very high
frequency data such as tick-by-tick data for USD/JPY. In this paper, we analyze the Sony bank USD/JPY rates, ignoring the
small deviations from the market price. We then show there is a similar non-trivial probability structure in the Sony bank
rate, in spite of the Sony bank rate's having less frequent and larger deviations than tick-by-tick data. However, this probability
structure is not found in the data which has been sampled from tick-by-tick data at the same rate as the Sony bank rate. Therefore,
the method of generating the Sony bank rate from the market rate has the potential for practical use since the method retains
the probability structure as the sampling frequency decreases. 相似文献
15.
A. P. Nawroth J. Peinke 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2006,50(1-2):147-151
A new approach is presented to describe the change in the statistics of the log return distribution of financial data as a
function of the timescale. To this purpose a measure is introduced, which quantifies the distance of a considered distribution
to a reference distribution. The existence of a small timescale regime is demonstrated, which exhibits different properties
compared to the normal timescale regime for timescales larger than one minute. This regime seems to be universal for individual
stocks. It is shown that the existence of this small timescale regime is not dependent on the special choice of the distance
measure or the reference distribution. These findings have important implications for risk analysis, in particular for the
probability of extreme events. 相似文献
16.
J. B. Satinover D. Sornette 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,60(3):369-384
Human beings like to believe they are in control of their
destiny. This ubiquitous trait seems to increase motivation and persistence,
and is probably evolutionarily adaptive [J.D. Taylor, S.E. Brown, Psych. Bull. 103, 193 (1988); A. Bandura,
Self-efficacy: the exercise of control (WH Freeman, New
York, 1997)]. But how good really is our
ability to control? How successful is our track record in these areas? There
is little understanding of when and under what circumstances we may
over-estimate [E. Langer, J. Pers. Soc. Psych. 7, 185 (1975)] or even lose our ability to control and optimize outcomes,
especially when they are the result of aggregations of individual
optimization processes. Here, we demonstrate analytically using the theory
of Markov Chains and by numerical simulations in two classes of games, the
Time-Horizon Minority Game [M.L. Hart, P. Jefferies, N.F. Johnson, Phys. A 311, 275 (2002)] and the Parrondo Game
[J.M.R. Parrondo, G.P. Harmer, D. Abbott, Phys. Rev. Lett.
85, 5226 (2000); J.M.R. Parrondo, How to cheat a bad mathematician (ISI, Italy, 1996)], that agents
who optimize their strategy based on past information may actually perform
worse than non-optimizing agents. In other words, low-entropy (more
informative) strategies under-perform high-entropy (or random) strategies.
This provides a precise definition of the “illusion of control” in certain
set-ups a priori defined to emphasize the importance of optimization.
An erratum to this article is available at . 相似文献
17.
S. Ciliberti M. Mézard 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2007,57(2):175-180
We use a replica approach to deal with portfolio optimization problems. A
given risk measure is minimized using empirical estimates of asset values
correlations. We study the phase transition which happens when the time
series is too short with respect to the size of the portfolio. We also study
the noise sensitivity of portfolio allocation when this transition is
approached. We consider explicitely the cases where the absolute deviation
and the conditional value-at-risk are chosen as a risk measure. We show how
the replica method can study a wide range of risk measures, and deal with
various types of time series correlations, including realistic ones with
volatility clustering. 相似文献
18.
M. Gligor M. Ausloos 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2008,63(4):533-539
GDP/capita correlations are investigated in various time windows (TW), for the time interval 1990–2005. The target group of
countries is the set of 25 EU members, 15 till 2004 plus the 10 countries which joined EU later on. The TW-means of the statistical
correlation coefficients are taken as the weights (links) of a fully connected network having the countries as nodes. Thereafter
we define and introduce the overlapping index of weighted network nodes. A cluster structure of EU countries is derived from the statistically relevant eigenvalues and
eigenvectors of the adjacency matrix. This may be considered to yield some information about the structure, stability and
evolution of the EU country clusters in a macroeconomic sense. 相似文献
19.
D. De Martino M. Marsili 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2008,65(4):595-600
We study how the volatility, node- or link-based, affects the evolution of social networks in simple models. The model describes
the competition betweenorder – promoted by the efforts of agents to coordinate – and disorder induced byvolatility in the
underlying social network.We find that when volatility affects mostly the decay of links, the model exhibit a sharp transition
between an ordered phase with a dense network and a disordered phase with a sparse network. When volatility is mostly node-based,
instead, only the symmetric (disordered) phase existsThese two regimes are separated by a second order phase transition of
unusual type, characterized by an order parameter critical exponent β = 0+.We argue that node volatility has the same effect in a broader class of models, and provide numerical evidence in this direction. 相似文献
20.
J. B. Satinover D. Sornette 《The European Physical Journal B - Condensed Matter and Complex Systems》2009,67(3):357-367
In the Minority, Majority and Dollar Games (MG, MAJG, $G) agents compete for rewards, acting in accord with the previously
best-performing of their strategies. Different aspects/kinds of real-world markets are modelled by these games. In the MG,
agents compete for scarce resources; in the MAJG agents imitate the group to exploit a trend; in the $G agents attempt to
predict and benefit both from trends and changes in the direction of a market. It has been previously shown that in the MG
for a reasonable number of preliminary time steps preceding equilibrium (Time Horizon MG, THMG), agents’ attempt to optimize
their gains by active strategy selection is “illusory”: the hypothetical gains of their strategies is greater on average than
agents’ actual average gains. Furthermore, if a small proportion of agents deliberately choose and act in accord with their
seemingly worst performing strategy, these outperform all other agents on average, and even attain mean positive gain, otherwise
rare for agents in the MG. This latter phenomenon raises the question as to how well the optimization procedure works in the
THMAJG and TH$G. We demonstrate that the illusion of control is absent in THMAJG and TH$G. This provides further clarification
of the kinds of situations subject to genuine control, and those not, in set-ups a priori defined to emphasize the importance
of optimization. 相似文献