首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
Given a connected undirected graph ϕ with vertex set N, cooperative games (N, v) are considered in which players can cooperate only when the corresponding vertices form a connected subgraph in the graph ϕ. For such games, two generalizations of the bargaining set M 1 i , which was introduced by Aumann and Maschler, are investigated.  相似文献   

2.
Leta=x 0<x 1<...<x N =b be a partition of the interval [a, b] and letL be a normalm-th order linear differential operator. The purpose of this note is to point out that spline functions in one variable need not be excluded to piecewise fits of functions belonging to the null spaceN(L * L) on each closed subinterval [x i,x i+1], 0in-1 but may be extended to piecewise fits of functions belonging toN(L i * L i) on each subinterval [x i,x i+1] provided theL i's are selected from a uniformly bounded family of normal linear differential operators. Furthermore when theL i's are so selected one obtains the usual integral relations and error estimates obtained for splines [2, 8 and 9] including the extended error estimates obtained by Swartz and Varga [10].  相似文献   

3.
Let Γ≡(N,v) be a cooperative game with the player set N and characteristic function v: 2NR. An imputation of the game is in the core if no subset of players could gain advantage by splitting from the grand coalition of all players. It is well known that, for the flow game (and equivalently, for the linear production game), the core is always non-empty and a solution in the core can be found in polynomial time. In this paper, we show that, given an imputation x, it is NP-complete to decide x is not a member of the core, for the flow game. And because of the specific reduction we constructed, the result also holds for the linear production game. Received: October 2000/Final version: March 2002  相似文献   

4.
Motivated by situations in which independent agents wish to cooperate in some uncertain endeavor over time, we study dynamic linear programming games, which generalize classical linear production games to multi-period settings under uncertainty. We specifically consider that players may have risk-averse attitudes towards uncertainty, and model this risk aversion using coherent conditional risk measures. For this setting, we study the strong sequential core, a natural extension of the core to dynamic settings. We characterize the strong sequential core as the set of allocations that satisfy a particular finite set of inequalities that depend on an auxiliary optimization model, and then leverage this characterization to establish sufficient conditions for emptiness and non-emptiness. Qualitatively, whereas the strong sequential core is always non-empty when players are risk-neutral, our results indicate that cooperation in the presence of risk aversion is much more difficult. We illustrate this with an application to cooperative newsvendor games, where we find that cooperation is possible when it least benefits players, and may be impossible when it offers more benefit.  相似文献   

5.
This paper presents a C^1-interpolation which preserves convexity to scattered convex data. The interpolant is local and explicitly described. The interpolating function si(x) is C^2 on each interval (xi, xi 1). Error will be O(h^2) when the function to he interpolated is C^3.  相似文献   

6.
《Quaestiones Mathematicae》2013,36(3):291-303
Abstract

Most homotopies considered in the literature are linear homotopies of the form h i (λ) = λx i + (1—λ)y i , 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1. Although these prove to be adequate in most instances, they lack direct geometric significance because {h i (λ) | 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1} are not orbits of a vector field. On the other hand, the nonlinear homotopy g i (s) = e s x i + (1—e s )y i ,—∞ ≤ s ≤ 0, are orbits of a vector field (i.e., dg i /ds = g i y i , g i (0) = x i ), and thus have direct geometric significance. This suggests that useful results can be obtained by replacing linear homotopy by transport along flows of smooth vector fields. The purpose of this paper is to elaborate on this simple idea. We define prehomotopy operators induced by vector fields on a manifold. These allow us to obtain finite transport relations and pre-Poincaré lemmas that generalize the classical results. They are shown to reproduce the classical results as asymptotic limits and to obtain representations of all solutions of complete systems of exterior differential equations on a star shaped region of a manifold.  相似文献   

7.
A linear extension x 1 x 2 x 3 ... of a partially ordered set (X, <) has a bump whenever x i <x i +1. We examine the problem of determining linear extensions with as few bumps as possible. Heuristic algorithms for approximate bump minimization are considered.  相似文献   

8.
Based on an R2-valued random sample {(yi,xi),1≤in} on the simple linear regression model yi=xiβ+α+εi with unknown error variables εi, least squares processes (LSPs) are introduced in D[0,1] for the unknown slope β and intercept α, as well as for the unknown β when α=0. These LSPs contain, in both cases, the classical least squares estimators (LSEs) for these parameters. It is assumed throughout that {(x,ε),(xi,εi),i≥1} are i.i.d. random vectors with independent components x and ε that both belong to the domain of attraction of the normal law, possibly both with infinite variances. Functional central limit theorems (FCLTs) are established for self-normalized type versions of the vector of the introduced LSPs for (β,α), as well as for their various marginal counterparts for each of the LSPs alone, respectively via uniform Euclidean norm and sup–norm approximations in probability. As consequences of the obtained FCLTs, joint and marginal central limit theorems (CLTs) are also discussed for Studentized and self-normalized type LSEs for the slope and intercept. Our FCLTs and CLTs provide a source for completely data-based asymptotic confidence intervals for β and α.  相似文献   

9.
Summary The objective in nonparametric regression is to infer a functiong(x) and itspth order derivativesg (g)(x),p≧1 fixed, on the basis of a finite collection of pairs {x i, g(xi)+Z i} i=1 n , where the noise componentsZ i satisfy certain modest assumptions and the domain pointsx i are selected non-randomly. This paper exhibits a new class of kernel estimatesg n (p) ,p≧0 fixed. The main theoretical results of this study are the rates of convergence obtained for mean square and strong consistency ofg n (p) each of them being uniform on the (0,1).  相似文献   

10.
In this paper an analogue of the bargaining setM 1 i is defined for cooperative games without side payments. An existence theorem is proved for games of pairs, while it is shown by an example that no general existence theorem holds.  相似文献   

11.
Suppose that K d is compact and that we are given a function fC(K) together with distinct points xiK, 1in. Radial basis interpolation consists of choosing a fixed (basis) function g : +→ and looking for a linear combination of the translates g(|x−xj|) which interpolates f at the given points. Specifically, we look for coefficients cj such that has the property that F(xi)=f(xi), 1in. The Fekete-type points of this process are those for which the associated interpolation matrix [g(|xi−xj|)]1i,jn has determinant as large as possible (in absolute value). In this work, we show that, in the univariate case, for a broad class of functions g, among all point sequences which are (strongly) asymptotically distributed according to a weight function, the equally spaced points give the asymptotically largest determinant. This gives strong evidence that the Fekete points themselves are indeed asymptotically equally spaced.  相似文献   

12.
An approximation of function u(x) as a Taylor series expansion about a point x0 at M points xi, ~ i = 1,2,…,M is used where xi are arbitrary‐spaced. This approximation is a linear system for the derivatives u(k) with an arbitrary accuracy. An analytical expression for the inverse matrix A ?1 where A = [Aik] = (xi ? x0)k is found. A finite‐difference approximation of derivatives u(k) of a given function u(x) at point x0 is derived in terms of the values u(xi). © 2006 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Numer Methods Partial Differential Eq, 2006  相似文献   

13.
Let P be a finite poset and let L={x 1<...n} be a linear extension of P. A bump in L is an ordered pair (x i , x i+1) where x ii+1 in P. The bump number of P is the least integer b(P), such that there exists a linear extension of P with b(P) bumps. We call L optimal if the number of bumps of L is b(P). We call L greedy if x i j for every j>i, whenever (x i, x i+1) is a bump. A poset P is called greedy if every greedy linear extension of P is optimal. Our main result is that in a greedy poset every optimal linear extension is greedy. As a consequence, we prove that every greedy poset of bump number k is the linear sum of k+1 greedy posets, each of bump number zero.This research (Math/1406/31) was supported by the Research Center, College of Science, King Saud University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia.  相似文献   

14.

Values of λ are determined for which there exist positive solutions of the 2mth order differential equation on a measure chain, (-1)m x ?2m (t)=λa(t)f(u(σ(t))), y? [0,1], satisfying α i+1 u ?21(0)+0, γ i+1 u ?21(σ(1))=0, 0≤im?1 with αi,βiii≥0, where a and f are positive valued, and both lim x-0+ (f(x)/x) and lim x-0+ (f(x)/x) exist.  相似文献   

15.
Every linear extension L: [x 1<x 2<...<x m ] of an ordered set P on m points arises from the simple algorithm: For each i with 0i<m, choose x i+1 as a minimal element of P–{x j :ji}. A linear extension is said to be greedy, if we also require that x i+1 covers x i in P whenever possible. The greedy dimension of an ordered set is defined as the minimum number of greedy linear extensions of P whose intersection is P. In this paper, we develop several inequalities bounding the greedy dimension of P as a function of other parameters of P. We show that the greedy dimension of P does not exceed the width of P. If A is an antichain in P and |P–A|2, we show that the greedy dimension of P does not exceed |P–A|. As a consequence, the greedy dimension of P does not exceed |P|/2 when |P|4. If the width of P–A is n and n2, we show that the greedy dimension of P does not exceed n 2+n. If A is the set of minimal elements of P, then this inequality can be strengthened to 2n–1. If A is the set of maximal elements, then the inequality can be further strengthened to n+1. Examples are presented to show that each of these inequalities is best possible.Research supported in part by the National Science Foundation under ISP-80110451.Research supported in part by the National Science Foundation under ISP-80110451 and DMS-8401281.  相似文献   

16.
In this paper we consider the problem of determining whether an unknown arithmetic circuit, for which we have oracle access, computes the identically zero polynomial. This problem is known as the black-box polynomial identity testing (PIT) problem. Our focus is on polynomials that can be written in the form f([`(x)]) = ?i = 1k hi ([`(x)]) ·gi ([`(x)])f(\bar x) = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^k {h_i (\bar x) \cdot g_i (\bar x)} , where each h i is a polynomial that depends on only ρ linear functions, and each g i is a product of linear functions (when h i = 1, for each i, then we get the class of depth-3 circuits with k multiplication gates, also known as ΣΠΣ(k) circuits, but the general case is much richer). When max i (deg(h i · g i )) = d we say that f is computable by a ΣΠΣ(k; d;ρ) circuit. We obtain the following results.
1.  A deterministic black-box identity testing algorithm for ΣΠΣ(k; d;ρ) circuits that runs in quasi-polynomial time (for ρ=polylog(n+d)). In particular this gives the first black-box quasi-polynomial time PIT algorithm for depth-3 circuits with k multiplication gates.  相似文献   

17.
A two-person positional game form g (with perfect information and without moves of chance) is modeled by a finite directed graph (digraph) whose vertices and arcs are interpreted as positions and moves, respectively. All simple directed cycles of this digraph together with its terminal positions form the set A of the outcomes. Each non-terminal position j is controlled by one of two players iI={1,2}. A strategy xi of a player iI involves selecting a move (j,j) in each position j controlled by i. We restrict both players to their pure positional strategies; in other words, a move (j,j) in a position j is deterministic (not random) and it can depend only on j (not on preceding positions or moves or on their numbers). For every pair of strategies (x1,x2), the selected moves uniquely define a play, that is, a directed path form a given initial position j0 to an outcome (a directed cycle or terminal vertex). This outcome aA is the result of the game corresponding to the chosen strategies, a=a(x1,x2). Furthermore, each player iI={1,2} has a real-valued utility function ui over A. Standardly, a game form g is called Nash-solvable if for every u=(u1,u2) the obtained game (g,u) has a Nash equilibrium (in pure positional strategies).A digraph (and the corresponding game form) is called symmetric if (j,j) is its arc whenever (j,j) is. In this paper we obtain necessary and sufficient conditions for Nash-solvability of symmetric cycle two-person game forms and show that these conditions can be verified in linear time in the size of the digraph.  相似文献   

18.
When modeling spatially distributed normal responses Yi in terms of vectors xi of explanatory variables, one may fit a linear model assuming independence, and then use the empirical variogram of the residuals to determine an appropriate parametric form for the autocorrelation function. Suppose, however, that the responses are not normally distributed—for example, Poisson or Bernoulli. One may model spatial dependence using a hierarchical generalized linear model in which, conditional on a latent Gaussian field Z = {Zi}, the Yi have independent distributions from the exponential family, with an appropriate link function connecting their conditional means with the linear predictors xtiβ + Zi. The question then is how to determine an appropriate model for the autocorrelation function of Z. The empirical variogram of the Yi is no longer appropriate, since (unless the link function is the identity) it is on the wrong scale. We propose here an alternative, the latent scale covariogram, whose graph reflects the autocorrelation structure of the underlying normal field. We illustrate its use on several real datasets, together with a simulated dataset, and obtain results quite different from those obtained using the variogram. Supplementary materials for this article are available online.  相似文献   

19.
Birkholl quadrature formulae (q.f.), which have algebraic degree of precision (ADP) greater than the number of values used, are studied. In particular, we construct a class of quadrature rules of ADP = 2n + 2r + 1 which are based on the information {ƒ(j)(−1), ƒ(j)(−1), j = 0, ..., r − 1 ; ƒ(xi), ƒ(2m)(xi), i = 1, ..., n}, where m is a positive integer and r = m, or r = m − 1. It is shown that the corresponding Birkhoff interpolation problems of the same type are not regular at the quadrature nodes. This means that the constructed quadrature formulae are not of interpolatory type. Finally, for each In, we prove the existence of a quadrature formula based on the information {ƒ(xi), ƒ(2m)(xi), i = 1, ..., 2m}, which has algebraic degree of precision 4m + 1.  相似文献   

20.
We consider the general optimization problem (P) of selecting a continuous function x over a -compact Hausdorff space T to a metric space A, from a feasible region X of such functions, so as to minimize a functional c on X. We require that X consist of a closed equicontinuous family of functions lying in the product (over T) of compact subsets Y t of A. (An important special case is the optimal control problem of finding a continuous time control function x that minimizes its associated discounted cost c(x) over the infinite horizon.) Relative to the uniform-on-compacta topology on the function space C(T,A) of continuous functions from T to A, the feasible region X is compact. Thus optimal solutions x * to (P) exist under the assumption that c is continuous. We wish to approximate such an x * by optimal solutions to a net {P i }, iI, of approximating problems of the form minxX i c i(x) for each iI, where (1) the net of sets {X i } I converges to X in the sense of Kuratowski and (2) the net {c i } I of functions converges to c uniformly on X. We show that for large i, any optimal solution x * i to the approximating problem (P i ) arbitrarily well approximates some optimal solution x * to (P). It follows that if (P) is well-posed, i.e., limsupX i * is a singleton {x *}, then any net {x i *} I of (P i )-optimal solutions converges in C(T,A) to x *. For this case, we construct a finite algorithm with the following property: given any prespecified error and any compact subset Q of T, our algorithm computes an i in I and an associated x i * in X i * which is within of x * on Q. We illustrate the theory and algorithm with a problem in continuous time production control over an infinite horizon.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号