首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 0 毫秒
1.
In this paper, we study solutions of strict noncooperative games that are played just once. The players are not allowed to communicate with each other. The main ingredient of our theory is the concept of rationalizing a set of strategies for each player of a game. We state an axiom based on this concept that every solution of a noncooperative game is required to satisfy. Strong Nash solvability is shown to be a sufficient condition for the rationalizing set to exist, but it is not necessary. Also, Nash solvability is neither necessary nor sufficient for the existence of the rationalizing set of a game. For a game with no solution (in our sense), a player is assumed to recourse to a standard of behavior. Some standards of behavior are examined and discussed.This work was sponsored by the United States Army under Contract No. DAAG29-75-C-0024 and by the National Science Foundation under Grant No. MCS-75-17385-A01. The author is grateful to J. C. Harsanyi for his comments and to S. M. Robinson for suggesting the problem.  相似文献   

2.
Systems that involve more than one decision maker are often optimized using the theory of games. In the traditional game theory, it is assumed that each player has a well-defined quantitative utility function over a set of the player decision space. Each player attempts to maximize/minimize his/her own expected utility and each is assumed to know the extensive game in full. At present, it cannot be claimed that the first assumption has been shown to be true in a wide variety of situations involving complex problems in economics, engineering, social and political sciences due to the difficulty inherent in defining an adequate utility function for each player in these types of problems. On the other hand, in many of such complex problems, each player has a heuristic knowledge of the desires of the other players and a heuristic knowledge of the control choices that they will make in order to meet their ends.In this paper, we utilize fuzzy set theory in order to incorporate the players' heuristic knowledge of decision making into the framework of conventional game theory or ordinal game theory. We define a new approach to N-person static fuzzy noncooperative games and develop a solution concept such as Nash for these types of games. We show that this general formulation of fuzzy noncooperative games can be applied to solve multidecision-making problems where no objective function is specified. The computational procedure is illustrated via application to a multiagent optimization problem dealing with the design and operation of future military operations.  相似文献   

3.
This paper gives wide characterization of n-person non-coalitional games with finite players’ strategy spaces and payoff functions having some concavity or convexity properties. The characterization is done in terms of the existence of two-point-strategy Nash equilibria, that is equilibria consisting only of mixed strategies with supports being one or two-point sets of players’ pure strategy spaces. The structure of such simple equilibria is discussed in different cases. The results obtained in the paper can be seen as a discrete counterpart of Glicksberg’s theorem and other known results about the existence of pure (or “almost pure”) Nash equilibria in continuous concave (convex) games with compact convex spaces of players’ pure strategies.  相似文献   

4.
This note provides a lemma on differential games which possess a feedback Nash equilibrium (FNE). In particular, it shows that (i) a class of games with a degenerate FNE can be constructucted from every game which has a nondegenerate FNE and (ii) a class of games with a nondegenerate FNE can be constructed from every game which has a degenerate FNE.The author would like to thank an anonymous referee for invaluable comments and suggestions.  相似文献   

5.
This paper uses submodularity to obtain monotonicity results for a class of Markovian queueing network service rate control problems. Nonlinear costs of queueing and service are allowed. In contrast to Weber and Stidham [14], our monotonicity theorem considers arbitrary directions in the state space (not just control directions), arrival routing problems, and certain uncontrolled service rates. We also show that, without service costs, transition-monotone controls can be described by simple control regions and switching functions. The theory is applied to queueing networks that arise in a manufacturing system that produces to a forecast of customer demand, and also to assembly and disassembly networks.  相似文献   

6.
We introduce a new class of games, congestion games with failures (CGFs), which allows for resource failures in congestion games. In a CGF, players share a common set of resources (service providers), where each service provider (SP) may fail with some known probability (that may be constant or depend on the congestion on the resource). For reliability reasons, a player may choose a subset of the SPs in order to try and perform his task. The cost of a player for utilizing any SP is a function of the total number of players using this SP. A main feature of this setting is that the cost for a player for successful completion of his task is the minimum of the costs of his successful attempts. We show that although CGFs do not, in general, admit a (generalized ordinal) potential function and the finite improvement property (and thus are not isomorphic to congestion games), they always possess a pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Moreover, every best reply dynamics converges to an equilibrium in any given CGF, and the SPs’ congestion experienced in different equilibria is (almost) unique. Furthermore, we provide an efficient procedure for computing a pure strategy equilibrium in CGFs and show that every best equilibrium (one minimizing the sum of the players’ disutilities) is semi-strong. Finally, for the subclass of symmetric CGFs we give a constructive characterization of best and worst equilibria.  相似文献   

7.
This paper considers the directed graphical structure of a game, called influence structure, where a directed edge from player i to player j indicates that player i may be able to affect j’s payoff via his unilateral change of strategies. We give a necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of pure-strategy Nash equilibrium of games having a directed graph in terms of the structure of that graph. We also discuss the relationship between the structure of graphs and potential games.  相似文献   

8.
We study nonzero-sum stopping games with randomized stopping strategies. The existence of Nash equilibrium and ɛ-equilibrium strategies are discussed under various assumptions on players random payoffs and utility functions dependent on the observed discrete time Markov process. Then we will present a model of a market game in which randomized stopping times are involved. The model is a mixture of a stochastic game and stopping game. Research supported by grant PBZ-KBN-016/P03/99.  相似文献   

9.
A method for choosing equilibria in strategic form games is proposed and axiomatically characterized. The method as well as the axioms are inspired by the Nash bargaining theory. The method can be applied to existing refinements of Nash equilibrium (e.g., perfect equilibrium) and also to other equilibrium concepts, like correlated equilibrium.The authors thank the reviewers for their comments, which led to an improvement of the paper.  相似文献   

10.
The aim of this contribution is an overview on Potential Games. This class of games is special, in fact we can investigate their properties by a unique function: the potential function. We consider several types of potential games: exact, ordinal, bayesian and hierarchical. Some results are generalized to multicriteria decisions.   相似文献   

11.
This paper considers discounted noncooperative stochastic games with uncountable state space and compact metric action spaces. We assume that the transition law is absolutely continuous with respect to some probability measure defined on the state space. We prove, under certain additional continuity and integrability conditions, that such games have -equilibrium stationary strategies for each >0. To prove this fact, we provide a method for approximating the original game by a sequence of finite or countable state games. The main result of this paper answers partially a question raised by Parthasarathy in Ref. 1.  相似文献   

12.
Strong and limit consistency in finite noncooperative games are studied. A solution is called strongly consistent if it is both consistent and conversely consistent (Ref. 1). We provide sufficient conditions on one-person behavior such that a strongly consistent solution is nonempty. We introduce limit consistency for normal form games and extensive form games. Roughly, this means that the solution can be approximated by strongly consistent solutions. We then show that the perfect and proper equilibrium correspondences in normal form games, as well as the weakly perfect and sequential equilibrium correspondences for extensive form games, are limit consistent.  相似文献   

13.
Consider an n-person stochastic game with Borel state space S, compact metric action sets A 1,A 2,,A n , and law of motion q such that the integral under q of every bounded Borel measurable function depends measurably on the initial state x and continuously on the actions (a 1,a 2,,a n ) of the players. If the payoff to each player i is 1 or 0 according to whether or not the stochastic process of states stays forever in a given Borel set G i , then there is an -equilibrium for every >0. AMS (1991) subject classification: 60G40, 91A60, 60E15, 46A55.  相似文献   

14.
For a noncooperative differential game, the value functions of the various players satisfy a system of Hamilton-Jacobi equations. In the present paper, we consider a class of infinite horizon games with nonlinear costs exponentially discounted in time. By the analysis of the value functions, we establish the existence of Nash equilibrium solutions in feedback form and provide results and counterexamples on their uniqueness and stability.  相似文献   

15.
There exists a Nash equilibrium (ε-Nash equilibrium) for every n-person stochastic game with a finite (countable) state space and finite action sets for the players if the payoff to each player i is one when the process of states remains in a given set of states G i and is zero otherwise. Received: December 2000  相似文献   

16.
Two-person nonzero-sum stochastic games with complete information are considered. It is shown that it is sufficient to search the equilibrium solutions in a class of deterministic strategy pairs — the so-calledintimidation strategy pairs. Furthermore, properties of the set of all equilibrium losses of such strategy pairs are proved.  相似文献   

17.
We present a class of countable state space stochastic games with discontinuous payoff functions satisfying some assumptions similar to the ones of Nikaido and Isoda for one-stage games. We prove that these games possess stationary equilibria. We show that after adding some concavity assumptions these equilibria are nonrandomized. Further, we present an example of input (or production) dynamic game satisfying the assumptions of our model. We give a closed-form solution for this game.  相似文献   

18.
An approximation of a general V-ergodic semi-Markov game with Borel state space by discrete-state space strongly-ergodic games is studied. The standard expected ratio-average criterion as well as the expected time-average criterion are considered. New theorems on the existence of ∊-equilibria are given.Communicated by D. A. CarlsonThe authors thank an anonymous referee for constructive comments. This work is supported by MEiN Grant 1P03A 01030.  相似文献   

19.
This paper provides an overview of the various shapes the best-reply multifunctions can take in 2×2×2 trimatrix games. It is shown that, unlike in 2×2 bimatrix games, the best replies to the opponents’ pure strategies do not completely determine the structure of the Nash equilibrium set.   相似文献   

20.
In this paper, we study the stability properties of the class of capital accumulation games introduced by Fershtman and Muller (Ref. 1). Both discrete and continuous time versions are discussed. It is shown that the open-loop Nash equilibrium solutions for both games are characterized by a general saddle-point property, a result best known from the turnpike literature in optimal growth theory. In the case of zero discount rates, an even stronger result can be derived: As long as the Hessian matrix of the instantaneous profit functions has a quasidominant diagonal, no pure imaginary roots are possible.The authors thank J. Boyd III, G. Feichtinger, S. Jørgensen, and G. Schwann for helpful comments. The first author acknowledges financial support from the Natural Science and Engineering Research Council of Canada, Grant No. OGP-0037342.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号