首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
We study a bargaining model where (i) players interim disagreement payoffs are stochastic and (ii) in any period, the proposer may postpone making an offer without losing the right to propose in the following period. This bargaining model has a generically unique perfect equilibrium payoff for each player, and the equilibrium outcome is inefficient in some cases, featuring a stochastically delayed agreement. We show that both the variation of players interim disagreement payoffs and the proposers ability to postpone making an offer without losing the right to propose are necessary for the existence of such a unique and inefficient perfect equilibrium outcome. Received April 2002/Final version April 2003  相似文献   

2.
We analyze bargaining situations in which the feasible set is known but the disagreement point is uncertain. By requiring that all agents, generally, be affected by the uncertainty in the same way, we characterize thelexicographic egalitarian solution.Discussions with Professors William Thomson and Hans Peters are gratefully acknowledged. However, I have full responsibility for any shortcomings.  相似文献   

3.
We provide a tool for studying properly discontinuous actions of non-compact groups on locally compact, connected and paracompact spaces, by embedding such an action in a suitable zero-dimensional compactification of the underlying space with pleasant properties. Precisely, given such an action we construct a zero-dimensional compactification of with the properties: (a) there exists an extension of the action on , (b) if is the set of the limit points of the orbits of the initial action in , then the restricted action remains properly discontinuous, is indivisible and equicontinuous with respect to the uniformity induced on by that of , and (c) is the maximal among the zero-dimensional compactifications of with these properties. Proper actions are usually embedded in the endpoint compactification of , in order to obtain topological invariants concerning the cardinality of the space of the ends of , provided that has an additional ``nice" property of rather local character (``property Z", i.e., every compact subset of is contained in a compact and connected one). If the considered space has this property, our new compactification coincides with the endpoint one. On the other hand, we give an example of a space not having the ``property Z" for which our compactification is different from the endpoint compactification. As an application, we show that the invariant concerning the cardinality of the ends of holds also for a class of actions strictly containing the properly discontinuous ones and for spaces not necessarily having ``property Z".

  相似文献   


4.
We will provide a lower bound for arbitrary proper actions in terms of the stratification by orbit types, and an upper bound for proper polar actions in terms of the equivariant LS-category of its generalized Weyl group. As an application we reprove a theorem of Singhof that determines the classical Lusternik-Schnirelmann category for U(n) and SU(n).  相似文献   

5.
Suppose Γ is a group acting on a set X. An r-labeling f:X→{1,2,…,r} of X is distinguishing (with respect to Γ) if the only label preserving permutation of X in Γ is the identity. The distinguishing number, DΓ(X), of the action of Γ on X is the minimum r for which there is an r-labeling which is distinguishing. This paper investigates the relation between the cardinality of a set X and the distinguishing numbers of group actions on X. For a positive integer n, let D(n) be the set of distinguishing numbers of transitive group actions on a set X of cardinality n, i.e., D(n)={DΓ(X):|X|=n and Γ acts transitively on X}. We prove that . Then we consider the problem of an arbitrary fixed group Γ acting on a large set. We prove that if for any action of Γ on a set Y, for each proper normal subgroup H of Γ, DH(Y)≤2, then there is an integer n such that for any set X with |X|≥n, for any action of Γ on X with no fixed points, DΓ(X)≤2.  相似文献   

6.
A classical result says that a free action of the circle S1 on a topological space X is geometrically classified by the orbit space B and by a cohomological class eH2(B,Z), the Euler class. When the action is not free we have a difficult open question:
(Π)
“Is the space X determined by the orbit space B and the Euler class?”
The main result of this work is a step towards the understanding of the above question in the category of unfolded pseudomanifolds. We prove that the orbit space B and the Euler class determine:
the intersection cohomology of X,
the real homotopy type of X.
  相似文献   

7.
We study the situation when the automorphism group of a recursively saturated structure acts on an ?‐tree. The cases of (?, <) and models of Peano Arithmetic are central in the paper. (© 2003 WILEY‐VCH Verlag GmbH & Co. KGaA, Weinheim)  相似文献   

8.
An isometric action of a compact Lie group on a Riemannian manifold is called hyperpolar if there exists a closed, connected submanifold that is flat in the induced metric and meets all orbits orthogonally. In this article, a classification of hyperpolar actions on the irreducible Riemannian symmetric spaces of compact type is given. Since on these symmetric spaces actions of cohomogeneity one are hyperpolar, i.e. normal geodesics are closed, we obtain a classification of the homogeneous hypersurfaces in these spaces by computing the cohomogeneity for all hyperpolar actions. This result implies a classification of the cohomogeneity one actions on compact strongly isotropy irreducible homogeneous spaces.

  相似文献   


9.
混沌群作用     
§ 1 IntroductionThispaperisthesequelto[1 ,2 ].Cairnsetal.[1] introducedthenotionofachaoticgroupactionasageneralizationofchaoticdynamicalsystems(seedefinitionbelow) .Theyshowedthatthecircledoesnotadmitachaoticactionofanygroup ,andconstructedachaoticactionofG =Z×…  相似文献   

10.
We show that any partial action on a topological space X is the restriction of a suitable global action, called enveloping action, that is essentially unique. In the case of C∗-algebras, we prove that any partial action has a unique enveloping action up to Morita equivalence, and that the corresponding reduced crossed products are Morita equivalent. The study of the enveloping action up to Morita equivalence reveals the form that Takai duality takes for partial actions. By applying our constructions, we prove that the reduced crossed product of the reduced cross-sectional algebra of a Fell bundle by the dual coaction is liminal, postliminal, or nuclear, if and only if so is the unit fiber of the bundle. We also give a non-commutative generalization of the well-known fact that the integral curves of a vector field on a compact manifold are defined on all of .  相似文献   

11.
We prove that, as in the case of global actions, any partial action gives rise to a groupoid provided with a Haar system, whose -algebra agrees with the crossed product by the partial action.

  相似文献   


12.
Certain Stiefel-Whitney classes of manifolds with smooth, effective toral actions are shown to be computable in terms of Poincare duals of fixed point sets of isotropy subgroups. As an application the toral degrees of symmetry of certain Dold manifolds are determined.  相似文献   

13.
We prove that, under certain conditions, if a compact connected Lie group acts effectively on a closed manifold, then there is no fixed point. Because two of the main conditions are satisfied by any Hamiltonian action on a closed symplectic manifold, the theorem applies nicely to such actions. The method of proof, however, is cohomological; and so the result applies more generally.

  相似文献   


14.
Suppose that an algebraic torus G acts algebraically on a projective manifold X with generically trivial stabilizers. Then the Zariski closure of the set of pairs {(x,y)∈X×X|y=gx for some gG} defines a nonzero equivariant cohomology class . We give an analogue of this construction in the case where X is a compact symplectic manifold endowed with a Hamiltonian action of a torus, whose complexification plays the role of G. We also prove that the Kirwan map sends the class [ΔG] to the class of the diagonal in each symplectic quotient. This allows to define a canonical right inverse of the Kirwan map.  相似文献   

15.
Abstract

We study compatible actions (introduced by Brown and Loday in their work on the non-abelian tensor product of groups) in the category of Lie algebras over a fixed ring. We describe the Peiffer product via a new diagrammatic approach, which specializes to the known definitions both in the case of groups and of Lie algebras. We then use this approach to transfer a result linking compatible actions and pairs of crossed modules over a common base object L from groups to Lie algebras. Finally, we show that the Peiffer product, naturally endowed with a crossed module structure, has the universal property of the coproduct in XModL(LieR).  相似文献   

16.

Which -dimensional orbi-spaces have effective symplectic - torus actions? As shown by Lerman and Tolman (1997) and Watson (1997), this question reduces to that of characterizing the finite subgroups of centralizers of tori in the real symplectic group . We resolve this question, and generalize our method to a calculation of the centralizers of all tori in .

  相似文献   


17.
In this paper we consider the effect of the `impatience ratio' I (of the worker discount factor to the firm discount factor) on the preferences of the players between two bargaining schemes in an asymmetric information wage bargaining context. The firm has private information about the worker's value and the worker makes wage demands. In the contact bargaining scheme, a wage demand which is accepted in one period is binding for all future periods (and hence the bargaining ends after acceptance of a wage demand). In the repeated bargaining scheme, the parties continue to bargain irrespective of whether the worker has been hired or not, and any accepted wage demand is only valid for the period in which it was accepted. We establish the following results under the assumption that the worker's value is uniformly distributed on an interval: When the firm is more patient than the worker (I<1) both parties prefer contract bargaining, and when the worker is more patient than the firm (I >1) both prefer repeated bargaining. For any value of I, the preferred type of bargaining gives the lower unemployment.  The work of Bae has already shown that when players are equally patient (I=1) the players are indifferent between the two schemes, regardless of the distribution of the worker's value. This paper shows that Bae's indifference result (Bae, 1991) cannot be extended to unequally patient players. Received: December 1996/Final version: October 1998  相似文献   

18.
Given a smooth closed -manifold , this article studies the extent to which certain numbers of the form are determined by the fixed-point set , where classifies the universal cover of , , is a polynomial in the Pontrjagin classes of , and is in the subalgebra of generated by . When , various vanishing theorems follow, giving obstructions to certain fixed-point-free actions. For example, if a fixed-point-free -action extends to an action by some semisimple compact Lie group , then . Similar vanishing results are obtained for spin manifolds admitting certain -actions.

  相似文献   


19.
20.
Let A be a symmetric hyperbolic matrix in SL(2, ℤ) and Γ the subgroup of SL(2, ℤ) generated by A. We aim to study the infinitesimal rigidity of the standard action of Γ on the torus . More precisely, we will consider the Sobolev Ws–infinitesimal rigidity of this action (that is to determine if the cohomology space H1(Γ,Ws (T M)) is trivial or not), and show that it is Ws–infinitesimally rigid only if 0 ≤ s < 1. A consequence will be that this action is not C–infinitesimally rigid. *I would like to thank A. El Kacimi for introducing me this problem about which we had many fruitful discussions.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号