共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
We study a bargaining model where (i) players interim disagreement payoffs are stochastic and (ii) in any period, the proposer may postpone making an offer without losing the right to propose in the following period. This bargaining model has a generically unique perfect equilibrium payoff for each player, and the equilibrium outcome is inefficient in some cases, featuring a stochastically delayed agreement. We show that both the variation of players interim disagreement payoffs and the proposers ability to postpone making an offer without losing the right to propose are necessary for the existence of such a unique and inefficient perfect equilibrium outcome.
Received April 2002/Final version April 2003 相似文献
2.
Y. Chun 《Mathematical Methods of Operations Research》1989,33(4):259-266
We analyze bargaining situations in which the feasible set is known but the disagreement point is uncertain. By requiring that all agents, generally, be affected by the uncertainty in the same way, we characterize thelexicographic egalitarian solution.Discussions with Professors William Thomson and Hans Peters are gratefully acknowledged. However, I have full responsibility for any shortcomings. 相似文献
3.
We will provide a lower bound for arbitrary proper actions in terms of the stratification by orbit types, and an upper bound for proper polar actions in terms of the equivariant LS-category of its generalized Weyl group. As an application we reprove a theorem of Singhof that determines the classical Lusternik-Schnirelmann category for U(n) and SU(n). 相似文献
4.
Suppose Γ is a group acting on a set X. An r-labeling f:X→{1,2,…,r} of X is distinguishing (with respect to Γ) if the only label preserving permutation of X in Γ is the identity. The distinguishing number, DΓ(X), of the action of Γ on X is the minimum r for which there is an r-labeling which is distinguishing. This paper investigates the relation between the cardinality of a set X and the distinguishing numbers of group actions on X. For a positive integer n, let D(n) be the set of distinguishing numbers of transitive group actions on a set X of cardinality n, i.e., D(n)={DΓ(X):|X|=n and Γ acts transitively on X}. We prove that . Then we consider the problem of an arbitrary fixed group Γ acting on a large set. We prove that if for any action of Γ on a set Y, for each proper normal subgroup H of Γ, DH(Y)≤2, then there is an integer n such that for any set X with |X|≥n, for any action of Γ on X with no fixed points, DΓ(X)≤2. 相似文献
5.
Gabriel Padilla 《Topology and its Applications》2007,154(15):2764-2770
A classical result says that a free action of the circle S1 on a topological space X is geometrically classified by the orbit space B and by a cohomological class e∈H2(B,Z), the Euler class. When the action is not free we have a difficult open question:
- (Π)
- “Is the space X determined by the orbit space B and the Euler class?”
- •
- the intersection cohomology of X,
- •
- the real homotopy type of X.
6.
§ 1 IntroductionThispaperisthesequelto[1 ,2 ].Cairnsetal.[1] introducedthenotionofachaoticgroupactionasageneralizationofchaoticdynamicalsystems(seedefinitionbelow) .Theyshowedthatthecircledoesnotadmitachaoticactionofanygroup ,andconstructedachaoticactionofG =Z×… 相似文献
7.
Fernando Abadie 《Journal of Functional Analysis》2003,197(1):14-67
We show that any partial action on a topological space X is the restriction of a suitable global action, called enveloping action, that is essentially unique. In the case of C∗-algebras, we prove that any partial action has a unique enveloping action up to Morita equivalence, and that the corresponding reduced crossed products are Morita equivalent. The study of the enveloping action up to Morita equivalence reveals the form that Takai duality takes for partial actions. By applying our constructions, we prove that the reduced crossed product of the reduced cross-sectional algebra of a Fell bundle by the dual coaction is liminal, postliminal, or nuclear, if and only if so is the unit fiber of the bundle. We also give a non-commutative generalization of the well-known fact that the integral curves of a vector field on a compact manifold are defined on all of . 相似文献
8.
Certain Stiefel-Whitney classes of manifolds with smooth, effective toral actions are shown to be computable in terms of Poincare duals of fixed point sets of isotropy subgroups. As an application the toral degrees of symmetry of certain Dold manifolds are determined. 相似文献
9.
I. Mundet i Riera 《Advances in Mathematics》2007,214(1):469-493
Suppose that an algebraic torus G acts algebraically on a projective manifold X with generically trivial stabilizers. Then the Zariski closure of the set of pairs {(x,y)∈X×X|y=gx for some g∈G} defines a nonzero equivariant cohomology class . We give an analogue of this construction in the case where X is a compact symplectic manifold endowed with a Hamiltonian action of a torus, whose complexification plays the role of G. We also prove that the Kirwan map sends the class [ΔG] to the class of the diagonal in each symplectic quotient. This allows to define a canonical right inverse of the Kirwan map. 相似文献
10.
Diane J. Reyniers 《International Journal of Game Theory》2000,29(2):165-176
In this paper we consider the effect of the `impatience ratio' I (of the worker discount factor to the firm discount factor)
on the preferences of the players between two bargaining schemes in an asymmetric information wage bargaining context. The
firm has private information about the worker's value and the worker makes wage demands. In the contact bargaining scheme,
a wage demand which is accepted in one period is binding for all future periods (and hence the bargaining ends after acceptance
of a wage demand). In the repeated bargaining scheme, the parties continue to bargain irrespective of whether the worker has
been hired or not, and any accepted wage demand is only valid for the period in which it was accepted. We establish the following
results under the assumption that the worker's value is uniformly distributed on an interval: When the firm is more patient
than the worker (I<1) both parties prefer contract bargaining, and when the worker is more patient than the firm (I >1) both prefer repeated bargaining. For any value of I, the preferred type of bargaining gives the lower unemployment.
The work of Bae has already shown that when players are equally patient (I=1) the players are indifferent between the two schemes, regardless of the distribution of the worker's value. This paper
shows that Bae's indifference result (Bae, 1991) cannot be extended to unequally patient players.
Received: December 1996/Final version: October 1998 相似文献
11.
12.
Cédric Rousseau 《Bulletin of the Brazilian Mathematical Society》2005,36(3):379-391
Let A be a symmetric hyperbolic matrix in SL(2, ℤ) and Γ the subgroup of SL(2, ℤ) generated by A. We aim to study the infinitesimal rigidity of the standard action of Γ on the torus
. More precisely, we will consider the Sobolev Ws–infinitesimal rigidity of this action (that is to determine if the cohomology space H1(Γ,Ws (T M)) is trivial or not), and show that it is Ws–infinitesimally rigid only if 0 ≤ s < 1. A consequence will be that this action is not C∞–infinitesimally rigid.
*I would like to thank A. El Kacimi for introducing me this problem about which we had many fruitful discussions. 相似文献
13.
定义了纤维丛的相配群胚的概念,从作用的角度研究了李群胚与主丛的关系;给出了一个泊松群胚在泊松流形上的作用是泊松作用的充要条件;文末得到了一些关于泊松流形上Casimir函数的结果. 相似文献
14.
Ian Hambleton 《Topology》2006,45(4):735-749
If G1 and G2 are finite groups with periodic Tate cohomology, then G1×G2 acts freely and smoothly on some product Sn×Sn. 相似文献
15.
Bangteng Xu 《Journal of Algebraic Combinatorics》2008,27(2):127-141
Sunder and Wildberger (J. Algebr. Comb. 18, 135–151, 2003) introduced the notion of actions of finite hypergroups, and studied maximal irreducible actions and *-actions. One of the main results of Sunder and Wildberger states that if a finite hypergroup K admits an irreducible action which is both a maximal action and a *-action, then K arises from an association scheme. In this paper we will first show that an irreducible maximal action must be a *-action, and hence improve Sunder and Wildberger’s result (Theorem 2.9). Another important type of actions is the so-called w-maximal actions. For a w-maximal action π:K→Aff (X), we will prove that π is faithful and |X|≥|K|, and |K| is the best possible lower bound of |X|. We will also discuss the strong connectivity of the digraphs induced by a w-maximal action. 相似文献
16.
The concept of (stable) weak containment for measure-preserving actions of a countable group Γ is analogous to the classical notion of (stable) weak containment of unitary representations. If Γ is amenable then the Rokhlin lemma shows that all essentially free actions are weakly equivalent. However if Γ is non-amenable then there can be many different weak and stable weak equivalence classes. Our main result is that the set of stable weak equivalence classes naturally admits the structure of a Choquet simplex. For example, when this simplex has only a countable set of extreme points but when Γ is a nonamenable free group, this simplex is the Poulsen simplex. We also show that when Γ contains a nonabelian free group, this simplex has uncountably many strongly ergodic essentially free extreme points. 相似文献
17.
Ruy Exel 《Bulletin of the Brazilian Mathematical Society》1999,30(1):99-124
The dual action of a locally compact abelian group, in the context of C*-algebraic bundles, is shown to satisfy an integrability property, similar to Rieffel's proper actions. The tools developed include a generalization of Bochner's integral as well as a Fourier inversion formula for operator valued maps.Partially supported by CNPq, Brazil. 相似文献
18.
Mohammad Javaheri 《Journal of Number Theory》2008,128(5):1146-1156
In this paper, we obtain strong density results for the orbits of real numbers under the action of the semigroup generated by the affine transformations T0(x)=x/a and T1(x)=bx+1, where a,b>1. These density results are formulated as generalizations of the Dirichlet approximation theorem and improve the results of Bergelson, Misiurewicz, and Senti. We show that for any x,u>0 there are infinitely many elements γ in the semigroup generated by T0 and T1 such that |γ(x)−u|<C(t1/|γ|−1), where C and t are constants independent of γ, and |γ| is the length of γ as a word in the semigroup. Finally, we discuss the problem of approximating an arbitrary real number by the ratios of prime numbers and the ratios of logarithms of prime numbers. 相似文献
19.
Sanja Konjik Michael Kunzinger 《Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications》2006,322(1):420-436
We study generalized group actions on differentiable manifolds in the Colombeau framework, extending previous work on flows of generalized vector fields and symmetry group analysis of generalized solutions. As an application, we analyze group invariant generalized functions in this setting. 相似文献
20.
Ruqu Wang 《International Journal of Game Theory》2000,29(2):229-240
In this paper, we analyze the class of all smooth separating sequential equilibria in a continuous-time bargaining model
with two-sided uncertainty. Trade between players occurs whenever there is surplus to be shared and delay is used to signal
their valuations. When the buyer and the seller have a common discount rate, we show that the final outcome is unique among
all these equilibria: the difference between the highest possible buyer's valuation and the lowest possible seller's valuation
always narrows down at a rate exactly equal to the discount rate. When their discount rates differ, the more patient side
always reveals his valuation first in the unique smooth separating equilibrium.
Received: November 1997/Final version: December 1999 相似文献