首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 11 毫秒
1.
In this work, a system of non‐linear difference equations is employed to model the opinion dynamics between a small group of agents (the target group) and a very persuasive agent (the indoctrinator). Two scenarios are investigated: the indoctrination of a homogeneous target group, in which each agent grants the same weight to his (or her) partner's opinion and the indoctrination of a heterogenous target group, in which each agent may grant a different weight to his or her partner's opinion. Simulations are performed to study the required times by the indoctrinator to convince a group. Initially, these groups are in a consensus about a doctrine different to that of the ideologist. The interactions between the agents are pairwise.  相似文献   

2.
Opinions are rarely binary; they can be held with different degrees of conviction, and this expanded attitude spectrum can affect the influence one opinion has on others. Our goal is to understand how different aspects of influence lead to recognizable spatio-temporal patterns of opinions and their strengths. To do this, we introduce a stochastic spatial agent-based model of opinion dynamics that includes a spectrum of opinion strengths and various possible rules for how the opinion strength of one individual affects the influence that this individual has on others. Through simulations, we find that even a small amount of amplification of opinion strength through interaction with like-minded neighbors can tip the scales in favor of polarization and deadlock.  相似文献   

3.
This study discusses the evolutionary nature of knowledge acquisition at micro and macro levels, and in particular when the process involves an artificial agent's interpretative devices. In order to accomplish this, we propose using an individual learning model (or inner‐world reconstruction model) that in our view overcomes neoclassic epistemological holdups and may increase the predictive power of computational economics, by letting an artificial agent's knowledge evolve by itself, irrespective of globally specified goals or individual motives of behavior; using simultaneous (or parallel) genetic algorithms (GA) to evolve a single agent's learning strategy, each GA with different general specifications, in a multiagent setting. © 2006 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity 11: 12–19, 2006  相似文献   

4.
5.
We analyze a bounded confidence model, introduced by Krause, on isolated time scales. In this model, each agent takes into account only the assessments of the agents whose opinions are not too far away from its own opinion. We show that the behavior of the model depends strongly on the graininess function μ: If μ takes values in the interval ]0,1], then our discrete time scale model behaves similarly to the classical one, but if μ takes values in ]1,+[, then the model has different properties. Simulations are performed to validate the theoretical results. Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   

6.
Organizations and Complexity: Searching for the Edge of Chaos   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
Traditional organizational theory advocates increased differentiation and horizontal integration for organizations in unstable environments or with uncertain technologies. This paper seeks to develop a better understanding of the relationship of group structure and the level of interdependency between individuals on group performance under various task complexities. Complexity theory in general, and NK models in particular, are introduced as theoretical frameworks that offer an explanation for group performance. Simulation models are developed, based on the communication network research of Bavelas (1948) and Leavitt (1952), to explore the effects of decentralization and interdependence. The simulation model developed here shows general consistency with previous human subject experiments. However, contrary to predictions, not all decentralized group structures perform well when undertaking complex task assignments. Structures that are highly connected (actors communicating with all others) perform much worse than those with a lower level of connection. Further experiments varying both the number of actors and the degree of interdependence between them find evidence of the edge of chaos. This research advances our understanding of organizations beyond earlier models by suggesting that there is an optimal range of interconnectedness between actors or tasks that explains the variation in performance. An intriguing result is that this optimal level of interdependence is fairly low, regardless of the size of the group.  相似文献   

7.
This paper focuses at the dynamics of attitude change in large groups. A multi-agent computer simulation has been developed as a tool to study hypothesis we take to study these dynamics. A major extension in comparison to earlier models is that Social Judgment Theory is being formalized to incorporate processes of assimilation and contrast in persuasion processes. Results demonstrate that the attitude structure of agents determines the occurrence of assimilation and contrast effects, which in turn cause a group of agents to reach consensus, to bipolarize, or to develop a number of subgroups sharing the same position. Subsequent experiments demonstrate the robustness of these effects for a different formalization of the social network, and the susceptibility for population size.This paper won the best paper award at NAACSOS 2004, Pittsburgh PA. NAACSOS is the main conference of the North American Association for Computational Social and Organizational Science.Wander Jager received his Ph.D. degree in Social Sciences in 2000 from the University of Groningen, the Netherlands. Dr. Jager is currently Associate Professor at the University of Groningen. His current application domain concerns marketing, innovation diffusion and social simulation. Dr. Jager has authored or co-authored various papers on market dynamics, diffusion processes, resource use and sustainable consumption.Frédéric Amblard received his Ph.D. degree in Multi-Agent Simulation in 2003 from Blaise Pascal University, Clermont-Ferrand, France. Dr. Amblard is currently Associate Professor at the University of Social Sciences in Toulouse and researcher associated to the CNRS-IRIT, Institute of Research in Computer Sciences in Toulouse. His current application domain now concerns Agent-Based Social Simulation. Dr. Amblard has authored or coauthored various research papers either in computer sciences, in physics or in sociology.A preceding version of this paper has been presented to the 2004 Conference of the North American Association for Computational Social and Organization Science, Pittsburgh, USA and received the best paper award from this conference.  相似文献   

8.
In the health informatics era, modeling longitudinal data remains problematic. The issue is method: health data are highly nonlinear and dynamic, multilevel and multidimensional, comprised of multiple major/minor trends, and causally complex—making curve fitting, modeling, and prediction difficult. The current study is fourth in a series exploring a case‐based density (CBD) approach for modeling complex trajectories, which has the following advantages: it can (1) convert databases into sets of cases (k dimensional row vectors; i.e., rows containing k elements); (2) compute the trajectory (velocity vector) for each case based on (3) a set of bio‐social variables called traces; (4) construct a theoretical map to explain these traces; (5) use vector quantization (i.e., k‐means, topographical neural nets) to longitudinally cluster case trajectories into major/minor trends; (6) employ genetic algorithms and ordinary differential equations to create a microscopic (vector field) model (the inverse problem) of these trajectories; (7) look for complex steady‐state behaviors (e.g., spiraling sources, etc) in the microscopic model; (8) draw from thermodynamics, synergetics and transport theory to translate the vector field (microscopic model) into the linear movement of macroscopic densities; (9) use the macroscopic model to simulate known and novel case‐based scenarios (the forward problem); and (10) construct multiple accounts of the data by linking the theoretical map and k dimensional profile with the macroscopic, microscopic and cluster models. Given the utility of this approach, our purpose here is to organize our method (as applied to recent research) so it can be employed by others. © 2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity 21: 160–180, 2016  相似文献   

9.
We study a simple model based upon the Lucas framework where heterogeneous agents behave rationally in a fully intertemporal setting but do not know other investors' personal preferences, wealth or investment portfolios. As a consequence, agents initially do not know the equilibrium asset pricing function and must make guesses, which they update via adaptive learning with constant gain. We demonstrate that even in this simple environment the economy can, depending on parameters, exhibit either stable convergence to equilibrium, or chaotic dynamical behavior of asset prices and trading volume without converging to the rational expectations equilibrium of the Lucas model. This contradicts the assertion that the Lucas model is stable in the face of modest deviations from the strong assumptions required to compute the equilibrium. © 2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity 19: 38–55, 2014  相似文献   

10.
The cerebellum and basal ganglia are reciprocally connected with the cerebral cortex, forming many loops that function as distributed processing modules. Here we present a detailed model of one microscopic loop between the motor cortex and the cerebellum, and we show how small arrays of these microscopic loops (CB modules) can be used to generate biologically plausible motor commands for controlling movement. A fundamental feature of CB modules is the presence of positive feedback loops between the cerebellar nucleus and the motor cortex. We use nonlinear dynamics to model one microscopic loop and to investigate its bistable properties. Simulations demonstrate an ability to program a motor command well in advance of command generation and an ability to vary command duration. However, control of command intensity is minimal, which could interfere with the control of movement velocity. To assess these hypotheses, we use a minimal nonlinear model of the neuromuscular (NM) system that translates motor commands into actual movements. Simulations of the combined CB‐NM modular model indicate that movement duration is readily controlled, whereas velocity is poorly controlled. We then explore how an array of eight CB‐NM modules can be used to control the direction and endpoint of a planar movement. In actuality, thousands of such microscopic loops function together as an array of adjustable pattern generators for programming and regulating the composite motor commands that control limb movements. We discuss the biological plausibility and limitations of the model. We also discuss ways in which an agent‐based representation can take advantage of the modularity in order to model this complex system. © 2008 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity, 2008  相似文献   

11.
We develop a computational model to explore how ethnic geography shapes the distribution of violence in civil war. We seed the model with disaggregated data on ethnic settlement patterns in Afghanistan and calibrate the model parameters to fit empirically observed locations of violence against civilians. Our simulation suggests that (i) political actors are more likely to attack civilians in heterogeneous areas where members of one ethnic group are exposed to members of a rival group; (ii) violence directed at civilians occurs with greater frequency in locations where one political actor exercises hegemonic but incomplete territorial control (relative to areas of complete or mixed control); and (iii) geographically concentrated ethnic minorities face a higher risk of violence. © 2012 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity, 2012  相似文献   

12.
13.
Two simple models of emergence and automated induction are described. In the first, an initially random process comes, over time, to emulate a deterministic process with noise. In the second, an induction algorithm is used to make unbiased best guess estimates of cellular automata rules generating a given time series of binary strings. The general conclusions are as follows: (1) that it may not be possible to distinguish between a stochastic process with selection and reinforcement and a noisy deterministic process; and (2) automated induction algorithms will often be vulnerable to errors of type 1 when faced with random data. In this second case, this leads to a method for study of the modeling class assumed in the induction algorithm. © 2006 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity 11: 44–57, 2006  相似文献   

14.
In a previous work on perturbation theory in population dynamics, we showed several plausible situations of preservation of the biodiversity. We give now an improved version of the method exhibiting a phenomenon of emergence of structured diversity. We display several (plausible in ethological or sociological contexts) examples of small modifications of the demographic equations that are emergent, that is, they lead to a limit state (the attractor) where the ‘spectators’ (i.e. to the individuals not concerned with the modification) vanish. In other words, even if the modification involves only a small number of individuals initially, the final pattern involves all the individuals. This behavior is easily understood in cases when the modification is concerned with some kind of symbiotic behavior, as it induces an advantage with respect to the ‘spectators’. But the phenomenon is very much general; we give examples of emergence in other contexts, involving predator/pray relations or other entangled relations, including an experimentally known example of subspecies of Escherichia coli. Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.  相似文献   

15.
This article considers the leader‐following consensus problem of heterogeneous multi‐agent systems. The proposed multi‐agent system is consisted of heterogeneous agents where each agents have their own nonlinear dynamic behavior. To overcome difficulty from heterogeneous nonlinear intrinsic dynamics of agents, a fuzzy disturbance observer is adopted. In addition, based on the Lyapunov stability theory, an adaptive control method is used to compensate the observation error caused by the difference between the unknown factor and estimated values. Two numerical examples are given to illustrate the effectiveness of the proposed method. © 2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity 19: 20–31, 2014  相似文献   

16.
This research explores how explaining an anchoring phenomena and engaging students in investigations, as central designs of a model‐based inquiry (MBI) unit, afforded or constrained the representation of scientific activity in the science classroom. This research is considered timely as recent standards documents and scholars in the field have highlighted the significance of identifying what features of scientific activity are important and how these can be represented for students in classrooms. Through taking advantage of qualitative research methods to closely examine the enactment of an MBI unit, both affordances and constraints were identified for each design. More specifically, explaining an anchoring phenomenon provided a context for more authentically framing the work of students, while investigations afforded students insight into the role these play in the refinement of models. Further, the teacher's attempts to support student reasoning and, at times, reasoning for students when they were found struggling were the most salient constraints identified connected to explaining an anchoring phenomenon and engaging students in investigations.  相似文献   

17.
In this paper, we study the global dynamics of a viral infection model with a latent period. The model has a nonlinear function which denotes the incidence rate of the virus infection in vivo. The basic reproduction number of the virus is identified and it is shown that the uninfected equilibrium is globally asymptotically stable if the basic reproduction number is equal to or less than unity. Moreover, the virus and infected cells eventually persist and there exists a unique infected equilibrium which is globally asymptotically stable if the basic reproduction number is greater than unity. The basic reproduction number determines the equilibrium that is globally asymptotically stable, even if there is a time delay in the infection.  相似文献   

18.
This article proposes a new mathematical theory of communication. The basic concepts of meaning and information are defined in terms of complex systems theory. Meaning of a message is defined as the attractor it generates in the receiving system; information is defined as the difference between a vector of expectation and one of perception. It can be sown that both concepts are determined by the topology of the receiving system. © 2010 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Complexity 16: 10–26, 2011  相似文献   

19.
In this work, we consider a one species population dynamics model with character dependence, spatial structure and a nonlocal renewal process arising as a boundary condition. The individual interaction are based on Boltzmann kinetic-type modeling. Using fixed point arguments and the div-rot lemma, we prove that our model admits a unique global nonnegative solution.  相似文献   

20.
ABSTRACT

In [A.S. Ackleh, M.I. Hossain, A. Veprauskas, and A. Zhang, Persistence and stability analysis of discrete-time predator-prey models: A study of population and evolutionary dynamics, J. Differ. Equ. Appl. 25 (2019), pp. 1568–1603.], we established conditions for the persistence and local asymptotic stability of the interior equilibrium for two discrete-time predator–prey models (one without and with evolution to resist toxicants). In the current paper, we provide a more in-depth analysis of these models, including global stability of equilibria, existence of cycles and chaos. Our main focus is to examine how the speed of evolution ν may impact population dynamics. For both models, we establish conditions under which the interior equilibrium is global asymptotically stable using perturbation analysis together with the construction of Lyapunov functions. For small ν, we show that the global dynamics of the evolutionary system are nothing but a continuous perturbation of the non-evolutionary system. However, when the speed of evolution is increased, we perform numerical studies which demonstrate that evolution may introduce rich dynamics including cyclic and chaotic behaviour that are not observed when evolution is absent.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号