首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
Weighted majority games have the property that players are totally ordered by the desirability relation (introduced by Isbell in [J.R. Isbell, A class of majority games, Quarterly Journal of Mathematics, 7 (1956) 183–187]) because weights induce it. Games for which this relation is total are called complete simple games. Taylor and Zwicker proved in [A.D. Taylor, W.S. Zwicker, Weighted voting, multicameral representation, and power, Games and Economic Behavior 5 (1993) 170–181] that every simple game (or monotonic finite hypergraph) can be represented by an intersection of weighted majority games and consider the dimension of a game as the needed minimum number of them to get it. They provide the existence of non-complete simple games of every dimension and left open the problem for complete simple games.  相似文献   

2.
A basic problem in the theory of simple games and other fields is to study whether a simple game (Boolean function) is weighted (linearly separable). A second related problem consists in studying whether a weighted game has a minimum integer realization. In this paper we simultaneously analyze both problems by using linear programming. For less than 9 voters, we find that there are 154 weighted games without minimum integer realization, but all of them have minimum normalized realization. Isbell in 1958 was the first to find a weighted game without a minimum normalized realization, he needed to consider 12 voters to construct a game with such a property. The main result of this work proves the existence of weighted games with this property with less than 12 voters. This research was partially supported by Grant MTM 2006-06064 of “Ministerio de Ciencia y Tecnología y el Fondo Europeo de Desarrollo Regional” and SGRC 2005-00651 of “Generalitat de Catalunya”, and by the Spanish “Ministerio de Ciencia y Tecnología” programmes ALINEX (TIN2005-05446 and TIN2006-11345).  相似文献   

3.
We consider simple games which are constructed as iterated weighted majority games. It turns out that every proper simple game can be obtained in this way. The minimal number of iterations necessary to obtain a given game is called the height of this game. We investigate the behaviour ofh (n), the maximal height of a simple game withn players.  相似文献   

4.
The rather new notion of effectivity function is related to the notion of simple game. Every effectivity function is associated with a simple game. So theory about simple games may be applicable to effectivity functions. E.g. if the effectivity function is additive, then the associated simple game is weighted. Via a characterization of weighted simple games it is possible to characterize maximal additive effectivity functions.Finally we characterize additive effectivity functions and their associated simple games.I thank G.J. Otten for useful comments and stimulating conversations.  相似文献   

5.
In this paper we give necessary and sufficient conditions for a simple game to have rough weights. We define two functions f(n) and g(n) that measure the deviation of a simple game from a weighted majority game and roughly weighted majority game, respectively. We formulate known results in terms of lower and upper bounds for these functions and improve those bounds. We also investigate rough weightedness of simple games with a small number of players.  相似文献   

6.
We prove some properties of simple games with a complete desirability relation, and investigate the relationships between the desirability of a simple game G and that of some simple games that are derived from G. We also provide an example of a proper simple game that has a complete and acyclic desirability relation but is not a weighted majority game.  相似文献   

7.
We consider Effort Games, a game‐theoretic model of cooperation in open environments, which is a variant of the principal‐agent problem from economic theory. In our multiagent domain, a common project depends on various tasks; carrying out certain subsets of the tasks completes the project successfully, while carrying out other subsets does not. The probability of carrying out a task is higher when the agent in charge of it exerts effort, at a certain cost for that agent. A central authority, called the principal, attempts to incentivize agents to exert effort, but can only reward agents based on the success of the entire project. We model this domain as a normal form game, where the payoffs for each strategy profile are defined based on the different probabilities of carrying out each task and on the boolean function that defines which task subsets complete the project, and which do not. We view this boolean function as a simple coalitional game, and call this game the underlying coalitional game. We suggest the Price of Myopia (PoM) as a measure of the influence the model of rationality has on the minimal payments the principal has to make in order to motivate the agents in such a domain to exert effort. We consider the computational complexity of testing whether exerting effort is a dominant strategy for an agent, and of finding a reward strategy for this domain, using either a dominant strategy equilibrium or using iterated elimination of dominated strategies. We show these problems are generally #P‐hard, and that they are at least as computationally hard as calculating the Banzhaf power index in the underlying coalitional game. We also show that in a certain restricted domain, where the underlying coalitional game is a weighted voting game with certain properties, it is possible to solve all of the above problems in polynomial time. We give bounds on PoM in weighted voting effort games, and provide simulation results regarding PoM in another restricted class of effort games, namely effort games played over Series‐Parallel Graphs (© 2009 WILEY‐VCH Verlag GmbH & Co. KGaA, Weinheim)  相似文献   

8.
The value of public information is studied by considering the equilibrium selections that maximize the weighted sum of players' payoffs. We show that the value of information can be deduced from the deterministic games where the uncertain parameters have given values. If the maximal weighted sum of equilibrium payoffs in deterministic games is convex then the value of information in any Bayesian game derived from the deterministic games is positive with respect to the selection. We also show the converse result that positive value of information implies convexity. Hence, the convexity of maximal weighted sum of payoffs in deterministic games fully characterizes the value of information with respect to considered selections. We also discuss the implications of our results when positive value of information means that for any equilibrium in a game with less information there is a Pareto dominant equilibrium in any game with more information.  相似文献   

9.
在合作博弈的一般模型中总是假设所有联盟都能形成。不过,在实际中由于受到一些因素的制约,有些联盟是不能形成的。基于此,Myerson提出了具有图通讯结构的合作博弈。Myerson值和Position值是超图博弈上的两个重要分配规则。2005年,Slikker给出了在图博弈上Position值的公理化刻画。但超图博弈上Position值的公理化刻画一直悬而未决。本文通过引入 “赋权平衡超边贡献公理”,并结合经典的“分支有效性”,提出了超图博弈上赋权Position值的公理化刻画。作为推论,解决了超图博弈上Position值的公理化刻画问题。  相似文献   

10.
It is a well-known result in the theory of simple games that a game is weighted if and only if it is trade robust. In this paper we propose a variant of trade robustness, that we call invariant-trade robustness, which is enough to determine whether a simple game is weighted. To test whether a simple game is invariant-trade robust we do not need to consider all winning coalitions; a reduced subset of minimal winning coalitions is enough.We make a comparison between the two methods (trade robustness and invariant-trade robustness) to check whether a simple game is weighted. We also provide by means of algorithms a full classification using both methods, for simple games with less than 8 voters according to the maximum level of (invariant-)trade robustness they achieve.  相似文献   

11.
An a priori system of unions or coalition structure is a partition of a finite set of players into disjoint coalitions which have made a prior commitment to cooperate in playing a game. This paper provides “ready-to-apply” procedures based on generating functions that are easily implementable to compute coalitional power indices in weighted multiple majority games. As an application of the proposed procedures, we calculate and compare coalitional power indices under the decision rules prescribed by the Treaty of Nice and the new rules proposed by the Council of the European Union.  相似文献   

12.
In this paper we deal with several classes of simple games; the first class is the one of ordered simple games (i.e. they admit of a complete desirability relation). The second class consists of all zero-sum games in the first one.First of all we introduce a natural partial order on both classes respectively and prove that this order relation admits a rank function. Also the first class turns out to be a rank symmetric lattice. These order relations induce fast algorithms to generate both classes of ordered games.Next we focus on the class of weighted majority games withn persons, which can be mapped onto the class of weighted majority zero-sum games withn+1 persons.To this end, we use in addition methods of linear programming, styling them for the special structure of ordered games. Thus, finally, we obtain algorithms, by combiningLP-methods and the partial order relation structure. These fast algorithms serve to test any ordered game for the weighted majority property. They provide a (frequently minimal) representation in case the answer to the test is affirmative.  相似文献   

13.
In this paper we consider standard fixed tree games, for which each vertex unequal to the root is inhabited by exactly one player. We present two weighted allocation rules, the weighted down-home allocation and the weighted neighbour-home allocation, both inspired by the painting story in Maschler et al. (1995) . We show, in a constructive way, that the core equals both the set of weighted down-home allocations and the set of weighted neighbour allocations. Since every weighted down-home allocation specifies a weighted Shapley value (Kalai and Samet (1988)) in a natural way, and vice versa, our results provide an alternative proof of the fact that the core of a standard fixed tree game equals the set of weighted Shapley values. The class of weighted neighbour allocations is a generalization of the nucleolus, in the sense that the latter is in this class as the special member where players have all equal weights.  相似文献   

14.
Equivalences between totally balanced games and flow games, and between monotonic games and pseudoflow games are well-known. This paper shows that for every totally monotonic game there exists an equivalent flow game and that for every monotonic game, there exists an equivalent flow-based secondary market game.  相似文献   

15.
In a fuzzy cooperative game the players may choose to partially participate in a coalition. A fuzzy coalition consists of a group of participating players along with their participation level. The characteristic function of a fuzzy game specifies the worth of each such coalition. This paper introduces well-known properties of classical cooperative games to the theory of fuzzy games, and studies their interrelations. It deals with convex games, exact games, games with a large core, extendable games and games with a stable core.  相似文献   

16.
An equivalence between simplen-person cooperative games and linear integer programs in 0–1 variables is presented and in particular the nucleolus and kernel are shown to be special valid inequalities of the corresponding 0–1 program. In the special case of weighted majority games, corresponding to knapsack inequalities, we show a further class of games for which the nucleolus is a representation of the game, and develop a single test to show when payoff vectors giving identical amounts or zero to each player are in the kernel. Finally we give an algorithm for computing the nucleolus which has been used successfully on weighted majority games with over twenty players.  相似文献   

17.
Dynamic process is an approach to cooperative games, and it can be defined as that which leads the players to a solution for cooperative games. Hwang et al. (2005) adopted Hamiache’s associated game (2001) to provide a dynamic process leading to the Shapley value. In this paper, we propose a dynamic transfer scheme on the basis of the dual similar associated game, to lead to any solution satisfying both the inessential game property and continuity, starting from an arbitrary efficient payoff vector.  相似文献   

18.
Two operators on the set ofn-person cooperative games are introduced, the minimarg operator and the maximarg operator. These operators can be seen as dual to each other. Some nice properties of these operators are given, and classes of games for which these operators yield convex (respectively, concave) games are considered. It is shown that, if these operators are applied iteratively on a game, in the limit one will yield a convex game and the other a concave game, and these two games will be dual to each other. Furthermore, it is proved that the convex games are precisely the fixed points of the minimarg operator and that the concave games are precisely the fixed points of the maximarg operator.  相似文献   

19.
Simple games are yes/no cooperative games which arise in many practical applications. Recently, we have used reduced ordered binary decision diagrams and quasi-reduced ordered binary decision diagrams (abbreviated as Robdds and Qobdds, respectively) for the representation of simple games and for the computation of some power indices. In the present paper, we continue this work. We show how further important computational problems on simple games can be solved using Qobdds, viz. the identification of some key players, the computation of the desirability relation on individuals, the test whether a simple game is proper and strong, respectively, and the computation of Qobdd-representations for the sets of all minimal winning coalitions, all shift-minimal winning coalitions and all blocking coalitions, respectively. Applications of these solutions include the computation of recent power indices based on shift-minimal winning coalitions and the test for linear separability of a directed simple game.  相似文献   

20.
This paper focuses on new characterizations of convex multi-choice games using the notions of exactness and superadditivity. Furthermore, level-increase monotonic allocation schemes (limas) on the class of convex multi-choice games are introduced and studied. It turns out that each element of the Weber set of such a game is extendable to a limas, and the (total) Shapley value for multi-choice games generates a limas for each convex multi-choice game.  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号